IV. Are Excess Profit Taxes in Line with Optimal Tax Theory?
A. Optimal Tax Theory
In his seminal book The Wealth of Nations, the 18th century British economist and philosopher Adam Smith attempted to identify the fundamental criteria that should govern a “rational” system of taxation and proposed the following four fundamental principles: (a) equity; (b) certainty; (c) convenience, and (d) neutrality. The following is a brief explanation of these principles in Adams’ own words:
I. The subjects of every state ought to contribute towards the support of the government, as nearly as possible, in proportion to their respective abilities; that is, in proportion to the revenue which they respectively enjoy under the protection of the state.…
II. The tax which each individual is bound to pay ought to be certain, and not arbitrary. The time of payment, the manner of payment, the quantity to be paid, ought all to be clear and plain to the contributor, and to every other person.…
III. Every tax ought to be levied at the time, or in the manner, in which it is most likely to be convenient for the contributor to pay it.…
IV. Every tax ought to be so contrived as both to take out and keep out of the pockets of the people as little as possible over and above what it brings into the public treasury of the state.…
These four maxims/canons have been consistently accepted by most scholars from various disciplines including law, economics, accounting, and political science. Thus, according to many scholars, an ideal tax system should be based on the “ability to pay” principle thereby justifying progressive rates to taxing income. It should also be based on the “benefit” principle, which assumes there should be a correlation between the taxes paid by the taxpayer and the services/benefits he/she receives (or is entitled to receive) from the government. Nevertheless, the issue of corporate income taxation was and still is more complex in terms of designing optimal taxation, as it is unclear who actually bears the burden of corporate income taxation.
Coincident with the introduction of an income tax, a vigorous discourse emerged as to how to design an “ideal” tax system and on how income should be calculated and taxed. The development of such discourse is generally referred to as the optimal tax theory. This Part begins by explaining the basic understanding of the optimal tax theory. It also questions whether and to what extent windfall taxes may be considered consistent with the standards of the optimal tax theory. The modern optimal tax scholarship dates back to economist and mathematician Frank Ramsey’s work a century ago, when income tax was in its infancy. The dominant concern raised by Ramsey was that the tax model (“optimal tax”) should minimize distortions to consumers’ pre-tax preferences. In other words, any such tax system should be neutral. However, it is impossible to ignore the fact that any income tax system directly or indirectly induces behavioral changes that possibly reduce tax revenues.
Following Ramsey’s work, the optimal tax theory was significantly advanced by the works of scholars Arthur Pigou and James Mirrlees. Pigou and Mirrlees introduced innovative (and distinct) analyses as to what constitutes optimal taxation, and these works have significantly changed the discourse and the way we think. Pigou focused on the role of taxation in regulating activities and internalizing negative or positive externalities resulting from taxpayers’ activities. By imposing corrective taxes, wrongdoers would pay for the “social costs” that result from their market transactions, and similarly, taxpayers that contribute to the economy would be entitled to tax subsidies or to tax holidays which would theoretically also incentivize other taxpayers to engage in such activities that (presumably) benefit society. As we will further elaborate in this Part, EPTs can indeed be viewed as corrective taxes or tax fines.
The work of Mirrlees on optimal taxation, by contrast, focused on the distributional impact taxes have by integrating the social welfare function. Mirrlees’ early work on optimal taxation integrated the “social welfare function” in analyzing optimal taxation, which represented the understanding of the important function taxes serve in making our society more just and economically fairer in protecting individuals’ wellbeing within the society and even to a certain extent, among other nations in the cross-border context. However, even though such ideas may be viewed intuitively, Mirrlees, for example, recommended that marginal tax rates on labor imposed on the highest earners should be lower than the equivalent rates on other earners, and his later additions regarding the interaction between income, wealth, and consumption taxation started a heated discourse among optimal tax scholars in the field of law, economics, and political science. It became clear that taxes cannot fulfill all functions and that, consequently, the optimal tax system should be comprised of a mixture of several taxes which would also be supplemented with social welfare payments that may assist the government in reducing wealth and income inequality to maximize the aggregate wellbeing of all members of society.
Pigou’s and Mirrlees’s works contributed to the understanding that taxes may not only serve to raise governmental receipts to fund public goods but may also serve (to the extent correctly tailored) to regulate activities and redistribute income and wealth thereby creating (at least in theory) a better society. Several decades later, additional optimal tax theorists focused on connecting theory and empirical work and offered different empirical models showing not only that taxes achieve different societal ends but also that the actual costs and benefits of taxes can be measured.
This empirical work invigorates optimal tax models with real-world data on behavioral responses to policy changes, including measures of elasticities (i.e., responsiveness) to alternative policies and measurements of deadweight loss (i.e., taxpayer responses that impose costs on taxpayers and the government), estimates of the costs of externalities that may be corrected through taxes, and survey and other data on social preferences for equality and redistribution. As a result, optimal tax models now benefit from the insights of behavioral economics, experimental studies, and survey and other data. Empirical studies have also influenced how optimal tax models account for externalities and the welfare benefits of taxation.
Two leading scholars who proceeded down this path are Louis Kaplow and Steven Shavell, who took Pigou’s and Mirrlees’s work a step further and argued that taxes play better than any other alternative regulatory framework in achieving such goals in the most efficient manner and with the least un-neutral interference. Shavell and Kaplow view corrective taxes as superior to any other regulatory framework as a means of controlling harmful externalities, and in our context, EPTs can clearly be viewed as corrective taxes, or at least as “tax fines,” that attempt to put pressure on corporations that use their monopolistic powers to overprice their services/goods.
However, while it seemed that initially corrective taxes could indeed be viewed as superior regulatory means to control externalities, there were other voices that criticized such taxes and discussed the harms such taxes may cause due to their regressive tendencies and possible negative effect on innovation and entrepreneurial corporate management decision-making (especially regarding innovative/pioneering measures which, to the extent successful, allow these taxpayers to enjoy superior market power by rendering innovative services and/or by selling innovative goods). Naturally, the application of corrective taxes can reduce corporate profitability and may undermine the cost-benefit analysis, which might deter such innovative investments. Therefore, we propose adopting a formula that would suspend the application of EPTs until any innovative R&D investment is fully recouped, including an entrepreneurial charge as described in the following Part IV(c).
B. The Distributional Impact of EPTs
The idea of “social fairness” played a significant role in designing progressive tax systems. That progressivity, however, has significantly eroded for various reasons over the past four decades in the United States and in most OECD member states, which also impacted non-OECD member states. The reduction in marginal personal tax rates, the cuts in most individual tax brackets (as well as the reduced rates for long term capital gains and qualified dividend distributions), the reduction in corporate tax rates, and the changes made to the federal estate (and gift) tax provisions have made the overall federal income tax system less progressive and closer to a “flat tax.”
Consider the historical trajectory of top marginal income tax rates. Initially 7% in 1913, the top marginal federal income tax rose quickly to 67% in 1917. The top rate reached 91% in the 1950’s, the declined to 70% in the 1960s and never fell below that for the entire decade of the 1970’s. Consistent with the story of the rise of the law and economics movement, however, Congress and the Reagan administration sharply reduced top marginal tax rates in the 1980’s, mainly in the name of efficiency. The rate dropped as low as 28% and has never risen above 39.6% since.
However, despite the abovementioned tax changes, it seems that most tax systems still attempt to redistribute wealth (also using the welfare systems) and strive to achieve fiscal fairness, but because the effectiveness of such goals have diminished over the years, the revival of EPTs may have an important role to play in this regard. As noted earlier, taxation is generally used to cover the cost of government, which provides social benefits to its citizens as well as to regulate certain activities that are perceived to be beneficial. Corrective taxes (such as EPTs) can be justified to the extent that the tax revenues raised reflect the true social costs/benefits that are byproduct of the activities.
Economists have long argued that Pigouvian taxes are better policy tools than traditional alternatives. For one thing, they present fewer opportunities for mistakes. Consider the most common traditional regulatory scheme: command-and-control. Quotas are command-and-control schemes, placing a ceiling on the maximum number of units a factory may produce. But to set the right quota, regulators must estimate both the total costs and benefits of production, determining at what point the former exceed the latter. This problem becomes especially acute when benefits vary from factory to factory—for example, if some produce better products than others. Then, an efficient quota requires separate, factory-by-factory benefit estimates. By contrast, Pigouvian regulators need to know only the harm from the marginal unit of pollution, not its private benefits. They can then set the tax equal to the harm, and factory owners, who know their own private benefits, will individually balance benefits and costs. Another advantage of Pigouvian taxes is that they are technology-forcing. A factory owner whose cap on production is fixed has no incentive to reduce per-unit emissions. Nor does a factory owner whose regulatory scheme requires, for example, a specific minimum suite of emission-reducing technologies, but no more. By contrast, a Pigouvian tax keyed to the factory’s actual emissions creates an incentive for the company to figure out ways to reduce its per-unit pollution. The promise of lower taxes for less emissions acts as a payment to the factory for investing in green technology.
Accordingly, successful implementation of corrective taxes depends on additional factors, including normal demand/supply elasticities, when there may be substitution for the goods/services consumed, and when the consumers may freely determine whether to continue to purchase the goods/services. The taxes raised should not exceed the direct or indirect costs incurred by the entity producing the goods/services subject to those taxes.
In our view, a corrective tax imposed on the consumption of basic needs or when there are no accessible alternative substitutes can be justified only to the extent that such a tax yields revenues sufficient to remedy whatever spillover negative consequences ensue to the taxpayers who consume such goods or services. If there are alternative substitutes (for example, public transportation), then a corrective tax on private transportation (to take this example one step further) hopefully will divert people to use public transportation thereby reducing pollution and traffic jams. In this context, EPTs can be regarded as corrective taxes, which are aimed to regulate above-normal returns of corporations under the assumption that such high profitability is generated mainly due to monopolistic or quasi-monopolistic powers (including location specific advantages), allowing these corporations to overprice their goods sold/services rendered by taking advantage of exceptional circumstances (including unexpected events such as wars, natural/ecological disasters, pandemics, etc.). However, corporate monopolistic power is also applicable when a corporation creates an invention that is entitled to exclusive protection for a period of years or when a corporation enjoys significant market share attributable to internal efficiencies. In those cases (to take but two examples), it seems like any above-normal profitability is not really abusive and should not expose those corporations to liability for an EPT.
In these circumstances, the imposition of EPTs, especially when the goods/services provided are life-saviors or can be considered as “basic needs,” would probably not lead to behavioral changes, and the imposition of such taxes regardless of the consumer’s ability to pay is regressive and serves to increase income inequalities. But (as explained in the following Part) to the extent that such EPT tax receipts can be earmarked and redirected to low-income taxpayers, the effect of such regressivity is diminished, and EPTs can even result in an overall progressive effect.
C. EPTs and Innovation
EPTs allow the government to tax supernormal returns corporations may generate. The idea behind such taxes assumes that corporations take advantage of their market power and overprice their services/goods. However, when it comes to services/goods that result from extensive investment in R&D processes, for example, such taxes would appear to be unwarranted since developers might not be fairly compensated for adventurous, risk-taking (and socially beneficial) behavior.
The fundamental ideas behind patent law aim to allow the inventor/developer economic incentives to invest time, money, and other resources in costly R&D processes, which (to the extent successful) would grant the inventor/developer the right to exclusively use/license/sell the patented idea for a limited period of time (generally 20 years). Awarding the entrepreneur monopolistic power in this regard makes the risky adventure more economically worthwhile for the entrepreneur (and for the developers and employees who joined with the entrepreneur), with positive spillover effects for society to boot. Experience shows that many important scientific (and other) discoveries started by mere coincidence or as side effects (or even accidents) in R&D activities that were designed for different ends and failed to achieve them.
However, as in many other regulatory fields, there are some criticisms of the standard protection period for patents, which some people view as allowing developers to overprice their good/services to an extent far greater than the costs of development, regulatory approval, and production, while at the same time others contend that the same protections do not allow the developers to fairly recoup their investments:
Patent law aims to encourage innovation patent protection grants an inventor exclusive right to use, sell, or license her invention for a limited time period of twenty years. This provides incentive for investment in innovation by allowing the inventor to enjoy the fruits of her labor. Yet, the patent system has been under fire in the last few decades by critics highlighting its major flaws and negative effects on innovation. The current system is criticized for being overly rigid—offering identical treatment to radically different inventions. This means patent protection is often either too narrow or overbroad. Patent protection is too narrow when it offers insufficient incentive for inventors to invest in research and development.
The problem with the current patent protection regime is twofold. The general 20-year period is insufficient for innovative processes when the resources invested in the process are very costly, and in that circumstance, the standard 20-year patent protection period does not allow the developers (and the investors who joined her or him) to recoup their investment. When this happens, it discourages entrepreneurs from engaging (and investors from investing) in such R&D work, and society at large can be denied a potential innovative solution to a current problem. But when the patent protection period awards exclusive rights protection far beyond the period of time needed to recoup investment costs and earn a substantial profit, the patent protection regime may be viewed as destructive in granting the entrepreneur monopolistic powers at the expense of the users/customers who may have difficulty affording the monopolistically priced products (or receive the services). This is especially true if there are insufficient (and presumably lower-priced) substitutes and the goods/services are crucial to society.
While the legal system developed a partial remedy for circumstances in which the 20-year protected period does not allow the taxpayer sufficient time to recoup its investment by allowing him or her file for an extension, the opposite is not true. That is, what about the situation where the developer can recoup its costs (and earn a substantial profit) in far less than 20 years? In that circumstance, the developer can realize monopolistic profits without a corresponding societal benefit (which has already been taken into account by the substantial profit the developer has already realized). Thus, perhaps a more adaptive regime should be adopted that would allow for different periods of patent protective measures. We believe that the idea raised by Marcowitz-Bitton, Kaplan, and Perel may be useful in this context (as we will explain in the next Part of this Article).
The issue of patent protection has attracted much attention over the past few years in the context of the global need to combat the pandemic and assist countries that lacked the necessary resources to purchase medical equipment, medicines, and diagnostics, not to mention the life-saving COVID-19 vaccines themselves, which had been recently developed and enjoyed patent protection. Even though the World Trade Organization (WTO) Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) awarded patent protection to the corporation that developed the RNA technology, the patent owners waived/suspended their exclusive rights for the mRNA vaccine technology during the global pandemic period. (The current mRNA technology is based on Hungarian, Japanese and American scientists’ research in different countries and is the product of cumulative, cross-national research.) However, despite the fact that COVID-19 vaccines were mainly purchased by governments and not by individuals, the pricing of COVID-19 vaccines were, to a certain degree, more supervised, thereby offsetting (to some extent at least) the monopolistic powers of the pharmaceutical companies:
Although research suggests that the unit cost of production of a mRNA vaccine dose is less than US$3, Pfizer prices it at US$19.50. Claiming that this is ‘pandemic pricing’ and yielding around 20% gross profit margin, Pfizer states that in a non-pandemic environment it would be normally priced between US$150 and US$175, with further potential to significantly improve profit margin due to lower cost per unit with rising volume of production. Even with the current price of less than US$20, Pfizer is expected to generate US$26 billion in vaccine revenue in 2021.
Accordingly, despite the waiver offered to COVID-19 vaccine developers for the use of mRNA vaccine technology, the pharmaceutical companies were still able to overprice the vaccines (in comparison to the direct and indirect costs of production of an mRNA vaccine dose), which was responsible for the high profitability of the vaccine and generated billions of dollars in revenue.
It thus seems that replacing the “fixed” patent protective period with a more flexible and comprehensive model is desirable not only in the patent law regulatory framework but also for taxation reasons as we will explain in the following Part. Such a comprehensive model is also desirable in an era of globalization in which it is relatively easy to evade applicable regulatory criteria by simply incorporating the entity in different jurisdictions that offer a more flexible regulatory approach that enables developers to increase their overall profitability.
V. A Proposed Model
When President Taft supported the legislation of the corporate income taxation in 1909, he referred to the following three justifications: (1) “[t]his is an excise tax upon the privilege of doing business as an artificial entity and of freedom from a general partnership liability enjoyed by those who own the stock”; (2) the corporate tax “imposes a burden at the source of the income at a time when the corporation is well able to pay and when collection is easy”; and (3) a corporate tax would enable the federal government to exercise supervision over corporations, mainly by obtaining information about corporate operations. President Taft devoted a whole paragraph of his message to Congress in describing the third argument:
Another merit of this tax is the federal supervision which must be exercised in order to make the law effective over the annual accounts and business transactions of all corporations. While the faculty of assuming a corporate form has been of the utmost utility in the business world, it is also true that substantially all of the abuses and all of the evils which have aroused the public to the necessity of reform were made possible by the use of this very faculty. If now, by a perfectly legitimate and effective system of taxation, we are incidentally able to possess the Government and the stockholders and the public of the knowledge of the real business transactions and the gains and profits of every corporation in the country, we have made a long step toward that supervisory control of corporations which may prevent a further abuse of power.
Similarly, we think the imposition of EPTs should be viewed not only as a means to finance governmental needs but also as a way to enable the federal government to supervise corporate operations and activities. The latter authority would provide a check on the taxpayers’ market powers, incentivize innovation (and thereby provide societal benefits), reduce capital and income inequality, and (in President Taft’s words) serve to prevent “further abuse of [corporate] power.” A similar idea was raised several years ago when it was suggested that the corporate income tax (and more specifically a progressive corporate income tax) should be used as an antitrust device to limit monopolization, anti-competitive measures, and unjustified price control of goods/services.
However, given the fact that most countries have reduced their marginal corporate income tax rates to approximately 20% (with an effective rate that is even lower), the political likelihood that dozens of corporate tax systems all over the world will be replaced with progressive systems with significantly higher marginal rates seems unrealistic. Accordingly, EPTs may indeed be the better solution for regulating powerful global corporate taxpayers that render vital technological services, life-saving treatment or cures, supply energy that allow basic living needs, and more. However, unlike the archaic designs of EPTs that were adopted in the past, we propose the following changes that would transform these taxes into effective vehicles for 21st century travel.
A. EPTs Should Be Legislated on All Sectors, on a Permanent Basis, in a Way That Would Achieve Behavioral Impact
We believe that the likelihood of replacing the existing corporate tax system with a progressive system, which imposes significant marginal tax rates, is unrealistic. Therefore, we recommend adopting EPTs as an integral part of our corporate system. We believe that the imposition of such taxes should be on a permanent basis and should not be limited to specific business sectors. Creating limitations on the applicability of EPTs would be an open invitation for political pressures that would generate inefficiencies, create avenues for manipulation, and undermine the ability of the tax authorities to audit these corporations to ensure proper enforcement.
We therefore call for adoption of a differential model that would measure empirically the benefits that such activities generate for society and the risk that such activities assume. The model would, for example, take into account, for purposes of determining the applicable rate of tax, both the amount invested, which to some extent reflects the risk taken by the developers and the investors, and the leverage ratio of the investment and the extent to which the local tax base is eroded following the leverage adjustment. We also recommend that until the invested amount is returned in full (plus a certain markup), EPTs would not be applicable. The proposed model would also consider to what extent the corporate taxpayer employs local employees/uses local service providers, whether the capital invested is injected domestically or overseas and directed at the corporate level or at the shareholder level, and whether the use of the proceeds from the disposition of the investment are reinvested in the local economy, overseas, or distributed directly to the shareholders for their use
It should be noted that this is not a closed list of considerations, and other considerations can be made, such as whose common denominator is the degree of contribution that the investment has made in the development and prosperity of the U.S. economy. For example, one can consider “green” activity that reduces pollution or an activity that employs local workers and take into account the wages given to workers (compared to minimum wage and with respect to education and the relevant industry) and any wage gaps between low-wage workers and board members who earn high salaries in those companies. As stated, this is not a closed list.
In this context, we also propose the adoption of “compensation” mechanisms that will reward shareholders and companies for qualifying activities. The intention is to adopt mechanisms that allow for the full return of the investment and possibly even an amount that exceeds the investment (and derived from the investment amount) without taxation or at a reduced tax rate and taxation of excess profits depending on the contribution of the investment to the U.S. economy. However, it must be ensured that the criteria adopted will be transparent to investors and that the multiplicity of these criteria will not create an overly complex model that will allow a broad cushion for tax planning on the one hand and significant reporting and enforcement costs on the other. However, as we pointed out earlier, unless the marginal EPTs rate exceeds 100% or the combination of the EPTs and the marginal cost in producing and selling the goods/rendering the services exceeds the price charged, corporations and governments would still be better off. That is why we propose that the marginal EPT rate (in addition to the standard corporate/personal income tax rate) imposed would generate a marginal deficit (make the corporations worse off) which may impact corporate managerial behavior.
B. Limiting Regressive Distributional Impact
EPTs are generally imposed when significant players take advantage of the market power and achieve returns above normal, which is primarily achieved due to special circumstances in times of conflict, war, or crises. However, as mentioned earlier, there are instances in which taxpayers enjoy exclusive market power from “patent protection” or technological superiority, and during that period, they engage in activities that serve to maintain their surplus market power.
However, as EPTs are generally imposed on goods/services that enjoy high demand/supply elasticities, the imposition of such taxes (fully or partly) may be shifted to the consumers, and imposition of such taxes proportionately among all taxpayers is regressive and will increase capital/income inequalities.
Therefore, we recommend that, to the extent that the imposition of such taxes would have regressive implications, the government should allocate tax revenues to amend the regressive implications. Such methodology is often referred to as tax earmarking. This means that the government will be “designating some or all of the collections from a specific tax for a specific expenditure, with the intention that the designation will continue into the future.” Alternatively, special transition rules could be adopted, or other targeted tax expenditures could be made that would benefit the injured low earners’ group. We are aware that governments are generally reticent to earmark tax revenues (unlike the usual process of pooling tax revenue into a general fund and then allocating it to various government spending programs). But except for instances in which the government purchases the services/goods (i.e., purchase of vaccines, financing war efforts), such methodology is significant. If revenues generated from EPTs are earmarked, they are necessarily directed away from the general fund, resulting in them being exempt from the ongoing review process that typically applies to general fund appropriations. Therefore, we suggest using earmarking methodology whenever EPTs have negative distributional impacts (regressive) so that the funds raised can be redirected to lower income households to reduce/eliminate the regressive impact (and even to increase progressivity to the extent possible).
C. Cross-Border Coordination/Cooperation
The main concern regarding the application of EPTs in cross-border settings is base erosion. Clearly, a multilateral adoption of such taxes would limit the ability of taxpayers to evade such taxes, but successful implementation of EPTs does not require multilateral cooperation (which is likely unrealistic anyway). However, in our view, successful implementation of EPTs can be reached unilaterally in which case limited cross-border coordination would be sufficient. If the tax system requires taxpayers to report their accounts on a consolidated basis, that would significantly alleviate concerns about EPTs base erosion and would reduce the concern that taxpayers would engage in a race-to-the-bottom tax competition.
However, assuming that all relevant taxpayers would be subject to EPTs (as many of the taxpayers are MNEs), a further question arises as to the way such taxes should be allocated among different tax jurisdictions. Furthermore, assuming that the calculation of EPTs and the imposition of EPTs would be based on a consolidated basis, we think it is time to depart from the arm’s length principle and the transfer pricing methodology and instead move into a unitary approach that would be based on formulary approach methodology:
A coordinated EPT would become a formulary apportionment approach, using sales by destination for allocating the tax base (except for location specific rents to be taxed at source). Such design shares the key characteristic of Pillar 1 under the 2021 Inclusive Framework agreement that consolidates a ‘residual’ profit of the multinational enterprise at the global level (defined as a predetermined profit margin of above 10 percent of global revenues) and allocates 25 percent of this residual to market countries (based on sales by destination). Thus, by going a step further from a unilateral EPT on the consolidated account of the multinational company to a coordinated EPT across countries (and allocating the tax base to market countries), we end up with a destination-based system that is similar in nature to the allocation idea of Pillar I.
As appealing as this recommendation may sound, we are cognizant of the difficulties in achieving a consensual formula and the experience in adopting a common consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB) in the European Union. We therefore recommend that such a formula should be based mainly on factors that can easily be sourced and not easily manipulated. That is why we would focus on allocating the tax base to the market countries, or in other words, to rely on a destination-based system that is similar in nature to the allocation idea of Pillar I.
We also wish to join the IMF Report recommendation to reconsider a deeper and more fundamental reform that would replace the current corporate tax system with an EPT corporate income tax system. Accordingly, we propose, for example, to gradually lower the corporate income tax rate (toward a zero-tax on the “normal return”) while possibly raising the tax rate on excess profit. Assuming such changes were implemented on multinationals globally, the IMF Report suggests that global tax revenue would then increase by over 4% of current global corporate income tax revenues. The Report also suggested that to the extent that EPTs would be imposed at 10% globally and allocated to countries on top of existing corporate income taxes on excess profit, the increase in global revenue is about 16% of current global corporate income tax revenue.
We believe that the likelihood of imposing such a reform on all businesses (including small scale and medium scale businesses) is politically unrealistic. However, imposition of EPTs on large scale multinationals that operate globally at progressive rates (which might even exceed 100% when necessary to achieve behavioral impact) and allocate it on a destination basis (among the different markets) is indeed achievable and may possibly lead to the replacement of the existing arm’s length principle and the transfer pricing regime with a unitary/consolidated account approach and multilateral adoption of a formulary apportionment methodology.
VI. Concluding Remarks
The introduction of windfall taxes dates to more than a century ago to the early phase of WWI as a transitory means to finance governmental needs and minimize unjustified enrichment to taxpayers who take advantage of the “world’s misery.” These taxes gained renewed interest and overwhelming popularity from dozens of countries from all over the world in the medical and pharmaceutical industry, oil and energy industry, banking industry, and more. However, while a century ago the imposition of such taxes on a territorial and transitory basis might have made sense, successful implementation of these taxes in the 21st century, in an age of globalization, requires certain changes and additional thought. Despite the EPTs limited scope in terms of revenues, period in which such taxes have been implemented, and the territorial application, scholarly literature criticized their design and suggested that they are not consistent with the principles constituting the optimal tax theory and in fact, can be viewed as arbitrary, lacking neutrality, and vulnerable to easy (and inexpensive) manipulation.
Our article views such taxes as corrective taxes and proposes certain changes in its design/implementation in an era of globalization. This article also wishes to highlight the negative implications such taxes may have in increasing inequality (due to its regressive nature) and disincentivizing innovation and R&D activities that benefit society. That is why we propose certain changes that will assist taxpayers in bearing the social costs of their activities rather than forcing society to bear them, encouraging multilateral coordination (not necessarily multilateral cooperation) to protect the EPT base in the cross-border context while also providing for a fairer allocation of the EPTs’ revenues among the relevant countries on a destination basis. We wish to conclude this article by saying that corrective taxation presents an important regulatory fiscal/economic tool and call on the legislators to treat it as such and not necessarily as a means to finance ad hoc governmental needs.