Sources: Based on data collected and measures created by Samuel Allen. See generally Allen, supra note 45. The real wage is the national weekly average manufacturing wage. Real Manufacturing Earnings and Real Expected Benefits were deflated by the Consumer Price Index (2000=100).
One of the major problems faced by workers was a relatively slow rise in their benefit payments for lost earnings. Most states had weekly maximum benefits, and the benefits were stated in the statutes in “nominal” values that were not adjusted for inflation. Until the 1960s, no states included clauses to adjust for inflation, and only a handful of states did so in the 1960s. There is always inertia in changing laws. In the case of workers’ compensation, the employers, workers, and insurers all had a stake, and so it often took time to come to a new compromise value. As a result, the states often would not change their weekly maximums for several years. After 1933, inflation became a problem because it eroded the purchasing power of the weekly maximum benefits listed in the statutes. In Delaware, for example, the weekly maximum was $13.50 in 1933 dollars in 1933 and did not change until it was raised to $18 in 1939; because of inflation, the purchasing power of the $13.50 benefit fell by nearly eight percent between 1933 and 1939. Delaware changed its benefits in 1939, 1942, 1946, 1950, 1956, and 1972. Each delay contributed to an erosion of benefits until the next increase was adopted. The worst erosion occurred between 1956 and 1972, when the weekly maximum benefit stayed fixed at $60. When Delaware first introduced the $60 maximum in 1956, it was higher than the average weekly wage in the state. By 1959, Delaware had started to limit benefits to below two-thirds of the average weekly wage. By 1971, the weekly maximum limited benefits to only thirty-nine percent of the average weekly wage. The purchasing power of the benefits was thirty-three percent lower than it had been when the $60 maximum was first introduced in 1956. Roughly half of the states had time spans when the weekly maximum did not change for at least ten years, often during the period covering the 1930s and 1940s. Louisiana, South Carolina, and Texas each had two spans of ten years or longer.
One of the consequences of this process was that benefits tended to stagnate relative to wages. Figure 2 shows indexes (1970=100) for national averages for a measure of real workers’ compensation benefits, real earnings for manufacturing workers, and the ratio of benefits to earnings. The measures are turned into “real” inflation-adjusted values using the Consumer Price Index (2000=100). The construction of the benefits measure is described in Appendix A. The long-term trend for both real benefits and real earnings was generally positive between 1930 and 1970. The ratio of benefits to earnings started out relatively high in 1930 and rose through 1933 because of a strong deflation. As inflation developed and many states kept their nominal weekly maximum benefits the same, the ratio dropped after 1933 and then dropped rapidly during the inflation of World War I. The ratio then fluctuated quite a bit. The states’ patterns of waiting multiple years to change nominal weekly maximums while wages continued to rise led to the drops in the benefit ratio. The ratio would then spike upward again when the states adjusted the weekly maximums. The problems with the benefit levels not keeping up with increases in the cost of living for long periods of time were one of the major complaints about workers’ compensation that led to several of the recommendations made the Burton Commission.
III. The Burton Commission
The Burton Commission was formed as part of the Occupational Safety and Health Act of 1970. As Michael Duff describes in his article in this issue, the Commission made nineteen essential recommendations for the workers’ compensation system. The recommendations that directly related to benefits included a call for full coverage for work-related diseases. Three of the recommendations called for maximum weekly benefits for three injury categories—total temporary disability, permanent total disability, and deaths—to be at least two-thirds of the state’s average weekly wage with a suggestion that by July 1, 1975, the maximum be at least 100% of the state’s weekly wage. The Commission called for total disability benefits to be paid for the duration of the worker’s disability or for life with no limits as to dollar amount or time. It also recommended that death benefits be paid until the spouse remarried, with an additional lump sum payment of two years of benefits at the time of marriage; further, the children should receive benefits until age eighteen or to twenty-five if they remained a dependent and were attending school. Finally, the Commission called for no statutory limit on time or dollar amounts for medical care or physical rehabilitation services.
In our view, the Commission was extremely successful at obtaining adoption of its recommendations relative to most federal commissions, which often tend to be ignored. In 1972, the average number of recommendations the states were following was 6.8 out of 19. By 1980, the average number followed had nearly doubled to 12.1. The adoption of the recommendations then stalled after 1980, such that the average number was 12.8 by 2004. Our sense is that the most powerful recommendations adopted were the calls for maximum weekly benefits to be tied to the state’s weekly wage. This “indexing” of the weekly maximum benefit allowed for automatic adjustments associated with inflation of wages and prices, and thus avoided the problems with inertia and interest group negotiations that kept the states from updating weekly maximums before 1970. The first state to index was Connecticut in 1960. By 1970, ten states were indexing. By 1980, eight years after the Burton Commission Report was published, over forty states were indexing. As of 2000, all states except Alaska, Arizona, California, Georgia, Indiana, Minnesota, and New York were indexing. Arizona and New York then adopted indexing in 2007, and it was then reintroduced by California in 2007 and Minnesota in 2013. In contrast to workers’ compensation, state unemployment insurance (UI) benefit maximums have been indexed in only about thirty states, and UI benefits have fallen behind wage and price growth to a much greater extent.
You can see the importance of indexing in the national averages in Figure 2. The index of real expected workers’ compensation benefits and the index of the ratio of benefits to manufacturing earnings jumped from 100 to 160 in the decade between 1970 and 1980. This increase means that real workers’ compensation benefits were sixty percent higher in 1980 than they were in 1970. Note that the real earnings indexed stayed the same—around 100—throughout that decade; thus workers’ compensation benefits were replacing sixty percent more of wages lost due to injury in 1980 than they had been in 1970. Both measures rose to around 180% of the 1970 measure over the next two decades, while a few more states joined in indexing. Given that the central goal of workers’ compensation is to provide aid to injured workers, the adoption of the Burton Commission’s recommendations to have weekly maximums move with the state’s weekly wage by themselves led to substantial enhancements in the programs.
IV. The Twenty-First Century
The trend toward following the Burton Commission recommendations began moving in the opposite direction around 2004, as eleven states reduced the number of recommendations they were following after that year. The backtracking was stimulated by employer complaints about the acceleration in workers’ compensation costs per injury during the 1990s. There were three main reasons for the rise. First, workers’ compensation medical costs were rising as fast or faster than the rapid five to six percent annual rise in general health care inflation between 1985 and 2000. As a result, the medical share of cash and medical costs rose from twenty-nine percent of workers’ compensation benefits in 1980 to forty-five percent circa 2000 and to fifty percent by 2010. Second, the move to indexing weekly maximum cash benefits meant that the nominal statutory benefits paid for each injury rose automatically at an average of around three percent per year. Third, increasing complaints about the procedural rules tended to give workers the benefit of the doubt in determining eligibility for benefits. Under the liberal construction rule, any ambiguity in workers’ compensation statutes or evidentiary uncertainty was to be resolved in favor of workers. Legal professionals claimed that abusive applications of the liberal construction rule exacerbated workers’ moral hazard and drove the state workers’ compensation system near to bankruptcy.
In trying to limit costs, employers were unlikely to be successful at getting others to agree to stop indexing of weekly maximum benefits. Once established, it is often difficult to change major features of programs because of the large number of stakeholders in those features. It would have been particularly difficult to stop the indexing because it would likely lead to a significant reduction in the growth in benefits. Employers found more success in following the health insurance strategies of setting medical fees and establishing physician networks, while challenging procedural rules related to burdens of proof that were more subtle in their impact and largely influenced only the disputed injury cases. By 2016, thirty-nine of the states had passed laws setting up medical fee schedules, nine had established physician networks, and over thirty had passed laws changing procedural rules.
A. What Caused the Downward Trends in Benefits Per Covered Workers
Workers’ compensation practitioners, scholars, and the press have expressed concerns that the Grand Bargain of workers’ compensation has been eroding since the early 2000s. This view has been heavily influenced by two types of information. The first is the decline in the inflation-adjusted national averages of cash and medical benefits per covered worker, as shown in Figure 3. The second is an index of workers’ compensation laws for each year between 2002 and 2014 created by Yue Qiu and Michael Grabell in 2015. In an online article at the ProPublica website that was based on the index, Grabell and Berkes concluded that many states had “slashed workers’ compensation benefits,” and were in a “race to the bottom.”
Figure 3 shows the distribution of funds for workers’ compensation divided by the number of people who are covered by workers’ compensation. The wage replacement benefits (nonmedical) are adjusted for inflation using the Consumer Price Index (CPI), and the medical benefits are adjusted for the specific CPI for medical treatments, which has risen faster than the overall CPI for several decades.
The benefits per covered worker experienced quite a reversal after the mid 1990s. Before the period shown on Figure 3, wage replacement benefits per covered worker had roughly doubled between 1940 and 1972, the year of the Burton Commission, and then doubled again through the mid 1990s after the states adopted many of the Commission’s recommendations. Similarly, real medical expenditures per covered worker rose about ten percent between 1940 and 1971 and then doubled between 1971 and 1992.
Since the mid-1990s, however, Figure 3 shows that both types of benefits per covered worker have declined. Between 1997 and 2016, the years when we could get detailed state-by-year data, the wage replacement benefits per covered worker have fallen thirty percent, and the medical benefits have fallen twenty-three percent. Why?