In the 1780s, one of the major weaknesses of the Articles of Confederation was that the federal government was unable to solve problems that spilled across state borders. Without the ability to prevent states from undermining the policies of their sister states or the federal government, the nation lived in existential dread of being defeated (either militarily or economically) by their neighboring states or by European powers. The United States Constitution was designed to remedy this and other inadequacies of the prior federal-state balance.
In his new book, The Collective-Action Constitution, professor Neil Siegel from Duke Law School argues that the primary structural purpose of the constitution is to empower the federal government to address “collective-action problems”: issues that that the states could not effectively address without collective effort. At the AJEI summit in November, Professor Siegel was joined by Judge Michelle Childs of the U.S. Court of Appeals for the D.C. Circuit to discuss his work.
The book’s cover features a colonial-era political cartoon that was published by Ben Franklin during the French and Indian War. It depicts a snake sectioned into several pieces, each labeled with the name of one of the British colonies. The cartoon was titled “JOIN, or DIE”—a message that continued to resonate with the founders during the revolutionary era as well. Without a unified government that could provide joint military protection and consistent national policies across all of the soon-to-be states, each would be under constant threat.
The book begins with a discussion of the Supreme Court’s foundational 1819 opinion in Marshall v. McCullough, 17 U.S. 316 (1819.) (Professor Siegel and Judge Childs discussed McCullough at the AJEI summit last year as well.) McCullough is arguably the most important Supreme Court decision in the nation’s history when it comes to structural constitutional matters. Justice John Marshall authored the opinion holding that the federal government had the implied power to create a national bank as a “necessary and proper” for carrying into execution its other powers, including the powers to “lay and collect taxes; to borrow money; to regulate commerce; to declare and conduct a war; and to raise and support armies and navies.” Id. at 407. It also held that Maryland could not undermine the aims of the federal bank by taxing it within the state’s borders, rejecting the argument that a state had any right to “retard, impede, burden, or in any manner control, the operations of the constitutional laws enacted by Congress.” Id. at 436.
The opinion in McCullough recognized that a part of the whole can’t tax the whole because it has non-representative incentives. Professor Seigel argues that the opposite of collective action is a perfectly competitive market. In such a system, each state has an interest in and the power to improve its own fortunes at the expense of the others and the whole, which triggers a host of classic economic market failures such as the free-rider problem, a race to the bottom, and the tragedy of the commons. Instead, as McCullough recognized, when the federal government acts as a whole, both costs and benefits are externalized broadly in order to ensure functioning institutions and address the exigencies of the union.
Other, less-obvious sections of the constitutional text can also reflect a collective-action rationale. The Enclaves Clause specifies that the seat of federal government must be in an enclave of ten square miles, separated from the states. The reason for that isn’t just that the federal government has to be located somewhere—it was motivated by an incident in which the dignity and authority of the federal government was vulnerable to being overridden by the power of a single state. In 1783, soldiers protesting a lack of back pay marched to Independence Hall in Philadelphia where the Continental Congress was meeting, operating under the Articles of Confederation. The soldiers blocked the doors and prevented the Congress from leaving. The state of Pennsylvania refused to send its state militia to provide protection, forcing the Congress to sneak away to New Jersey. The Enclaves Clause was in part designed to avoid such a “degrading spectacle of a fugitive congress.”