Emerging Regulatory Landscape: Two Examples
To better appreciate regulatory challenges in the sharing economy, consider two particularly prominent examples of the legal system adjusting in real time to disruption: the contested relationship between service providers and platforms and the local impacts of the spread of the platform short-term rental market. The first example cuts across most sectors of the sharing economy, while the second reveals a variety of challenges in a single sector. In both instances a significant degree of regulatory uncertainty remains as courts have reached differing conclusions and new regulatory challenges continue to arise.
Gig Workers: Employees or Independent Contractors?
One persistent legal question underlying the sharing economy is whether providers of services facilitated through platform companies — drivers on Uber and Lyft; delivery people on GrubHub and Postmates; cleaners, movers, handymen, and other service providers on Taskrabbit, Handy, and Thumbtack, among others — are employees of those platforms or independent contractors. The legal tests for determining employment status vary by the relevant federal or state statutes at issue in areas such as minimum wage and overtime, antidiscrimination protections, workers’ compensation, unemployment insurance, collective bargaining rights, and other employment-based regulations.
A common default approach that courts take to this determination examines the extent of a company’s control over someone’s work, considering factors like the skill required; the source of the instrumentalities and tools; the location of the work; the duration of the relationship between the parties; whether the hiring party has the right to assign additional projects to the hired party; the extent of the hired party’s discretion over when and how long to work; the method of payment; the hired party’s role in hiring and paying assistants; whether the work is part of the regular business of the hiring party; whether the hiring party is in business; the provision of employee benefits; and the tax treatment of the hired party.
In other instances, statutes provide more detailed and specific guidance to determine an employment relationship, often aimed at ensuring broad coverage.
Employee advocates have argued that sharing economy companies assert control over many of the most central aspects of how providers operate on platforms, including, in many instances, the fees that providers charge, performance standards, pay rates, and other traditional indicia of employment relations. Platform companies counter that because providers themselves decide “when, where, and how long they work,” they should be considered independent contractors. Courts and agencies have not reached a consensus on these arguments, and platform companies have responded by seeking statutory or regulatory changes in several states to codify the status of providers as independent contractors.
Home Sharing: The Local Regulatory Landscape
While debates over worker classification involve the relationship between platform companies and service providers, a separate set of regulatory skirmishes has pitted platforms, providers and users against the broader community. In the realm of short-term rentals, there is growing concern among local officials that as companies like Airbnb and Vrbo proliferate, they are moving existing housing out of the long-term rental market. This has the potential to exacerbate housing shortages and negatively affect affordability. The effect of short-term rentals on housing costs depends in part on the share of such rentals that are full-unit listings removed from the long-term rental market or rentals of a room where someone otherwise lives.
One of the key challenges for local officials has been crafting regulations that effectively distinguish between hosts occasionally renting spare bedrooms and people and companies renting out multiple units on the platform.
One way that regulators have made this distinction has been by imposing fees that vary based upon the intensity of use, for example, charging a larger licensing fee or higher tax rate for hosts who rent their unit more than a specified number of nights in a year. Such measures may more effectively discourage the conversion of long-term rentals to short-term rentals.
But such measures can prove difficult to administer. Underscoring this point, a proposed measure in Massachusetts that would have scaled a range of state and local taxes based upon intensity of use failed and was replaced by a significantly simpler framework that simply applies the equivalent of the hotel tax to short-term rentals, exempting hosts that rent a limited number of nights annually.
In contrast with more customized regulatory responses, which might better target particular concerns, some local governments have chosen to impose outright bans on unhosted short-term rentals or prohibitions on whole-unit rentals in specific neighborhoods. Others have sought to limit the concentration of short-term rentals at the building or neighborhood level.
As they seek to limit the location and intensity of short-term rentals, local and state regulators have also confronted challenges in obtaining the data necessary to ensure compliance. Regulatory frameworks often include a requirement that property owners register with the city or state. Registration systems can enable local governments to obtain data about the location of rentals throughout the city and, to a lesser degree, the intensity of their use.
Local governments also have imposed requirements that potential hosts include their registration number in any online listing and that platforms remove listings that lack such a number. However, platform companies have challenged these requirements and the penalty fees for listings that do not include a valid registration number in court on grounds that the ordinances, by forcing the platforms to monitor third-party content, violate section 230 of the Communications Decency Act (47 U.S.C. § 230).
The U.S. Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit recently rejected this claim in HomeAway.com v. City of Santa Monica, declaring that section 230 did not bar enforcement of a Santa Monica ordinance prohibiting platforms from facilitating short-term rentals that were not licensed by the city.
[T]he Ordinance does not require the Platforms to monitor third-party content and thus falls outside of the CDA’s immunity. The Ordinance prohibits processing transactions for unregistered properties. It does not require the Platforms to review the content provided by the hosts of listings on their websites. Rather, the only monitoring that appears necessary in order to comply with the Ordinance relates to incoming requests to complete a booking transaction — content that, while resulting from the third-party listings, is distinct, internal, and nonpublic.
Airbnb chose to settle a separate lawsuit against San Francisco, agreeing to help enforce registration laws by collecting data on hosts and sharing it with the city, as well as deactivating listings that lack a valid registration. While data sharing remains a flash point in disputes between sharing economy firms and local governments, in the contexts of STRs and TNCs, some larger cities have been successful in obtaining data directly from firms, often threatening to shut down their operations.
In other cases, Airbnb and HomeAway have challenged data-collection requirements by bringing claims under the Fourth Amendment. In January 2019, the companies received a preliminary injunction from a federal district court, barring New York City from enforcing part of a July 2018 ordinance that would require the platforms to turn over data monthly regarding hosts and listings. New York City responded by promptly issuing a subpoena to Airbnb and HomeAway for data regarding listings in the city.
Conclusion: Lessons for Public Lawyers
A few lessons can be drawn from the challenges that regulators have confronted in responding to the sharing economy’s transformation of a diverse range of business sectors. It is important for public lawyers to take a holistic view of these regulatory challenges and of the sharing economy’s effects.
Platform companies often seek to leverage ambiguity about regulatory coverage and, at times, regulatory gaps genuinely exist. As important as it is for public lawyers and policymakers to ensure that new business models operate within regulatory bounds, emerging sectors can cast existing regulations in a new light. The sharing economy thus has the potential not only to disrupt existing regulatory regimes but also to prompt improvements, and the data produced by sharing economy firms may improve the targeting and enforcement of regulations well beyond the platforms themselves.
The sharing economy, like much technological innovation, moves rapidly, so public lawyers should count on continued innovation and be prepared to address the concomitant issues. The rapid rise of microtransit platforms offering e-scooters and dockless bike shares, for example, may make urban transportation more sustainable, or it may simply clog local sidewalks, but regulators can anticipate the primary challenges that they pose, applying lessons from earlier waves of platform economy transportation companies. Those lessons, in turn, should help inform responses to the next revolution, such as autonomous vehicles.