III. Legal Framework
Approval of the TSMC project is subject to the City of Phoenix’s permitting decisions. In turn, takings law constrains what the state and local officials can require of developers.
A. Zoning Law
An outgrowth of the police power, states have largely delegated their zoning authority to local governments. Phoenix’s City Council makes zoning decisions based on recommendations by the Planning Commission, which is an appointed body. The Phoenix General Plan, which is implemented and enforced through ordinances, broadly guides these zoning decisions. State law requires that the General Plan be updated or readopted every 10 years by a public vote; voters approved the most recent update in 2015.
The 2015 General Plan identified three “Community Benefits”: Prosperity, Health, and Environment. As part of the latter, it identified climate change as a “significant challenge,” and both water resource planning and ecosystem protection as “[o]pportunities.” TSMC’s development lies at the intersection of two core values: “strengthen[ing] our local economy” and “build[ing] the sustainable desert city.”
The General Plan also calls for the City to “[p]artner with the private sector to responsibly develop new infrastructure and water supplies that accommodates growth in a fiscally prudent and sensible manner.” As part of this, it should “[e]ncourage water efficient building and site design.” Examples of ordinances enforcing these principles include xeriscaping requirements for public rights-of-way and a requirement that City water customers keep customer-side water infrastructure in good repair.
The City’s Water Resources Acquisition Fee (WRAF) program implements these values during the permitting process. WRAF is an impact fee collected in certain growth areas to ensure that developers pay their proportionate share of their impact on Phoenix’s water infrastructure and supplies. Currently, only off-project development is subject to WRAF, reflecting the challenges associated with securing non-SRP water.
Alternatively, developers can show their project “will have features that provide permanent reduction in net annual water demand on the City.” Such features include “[w]ater-conserving plumbing fixtures” or “[n]on-City water resources procured by the developer which . . . partially or wholly satisfy the proposed development’s water resource needs.” The water savings from these “features” are credited against the project’s WRAF. Thus, akin to a WND scheme, a developer has two options: reduce or pay.
Unfortunately, because of statutory limitations on development fees, WRAF revenue can only be used for water rights acquisition, related infrastructure, and water efficiency programs; revenue is not available for conservation-driven offset actions. Notably, these statutory limits are largely crafted to ensure that development fees do not constitute a taking. Thus, the next part considers whether a more ambitious and clearly articulated WND mandate would be constitutionally viable.
B. U.S. Takings Clause
The federal Takings Clause succinctly states, “[N]or shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation.” Historically, it applied to per se, physical takings of land. More recently, a doctrine has emerged for regulations that “go ‘too far’” and “restrict[] a property owner’s ability to use his own property.” The U.S. Supreme Court’s most recent takings decision, Cedar Point Nursery v. Hassid, purportedly clarified this distinction but arguably muddied it. This article sidesteps these new issues by considering water-management policies lacking in any physical appropriation, however temporary.
Two cases are hallmarks of the U.S. Supreme Court’s approach to zoning exactions: Nollan v. California Coastal Commission and Dolan v. City of Tigard. Nollan introduced the requirement that a regulation bears a “rational nexus” to a legitimate state interest, and Dolan added a proportionality standard. In both, a project’s anticipated burden, or impact, is the relevant baseline.
Here, there is a clear nexus between mandated water-neutral development and TSMC’s impact on the City of Phoenix’s water infrastructure and water supply. Unlike the “psychological barrier” to beach access in Nollan, TSMC’s water demand is quantifiable and tangible. And by nature, WND requirements are proportional. Conversely, a net-positive mandate would face both nexus and proportionality problems: once a project achieves water neutrality, it cannot pose a burden to the government. With no burden, there can be no nexus, and no exaction can be proportional. Thus, mandatory water-positive development programs are likely to be unconstitutional takings without just compensation.
Perhaps surprisingly, public use is not a condition precedent for a lawful taking. In Kelo v. City of New London, the Court approved the use of eminent domain to seize private land to then sell to private developers. It reasoned that the economic benefits of private development were a “public use” within the meaning of the Takings Clause. Notably, the Fifth Amendment Takings Clause does not require literal public use, but rather a “public purpose.”
While “public purpose” is not the sole trigger for a lawful taking, and Kelo squarely involved traditional condemnation, it is helpful to contemplate Kelo’s potential reach. Here, at a minimum, WND policies further a public purpose, and some policies may directly further a public use. For example, a law dedicating impact fee revenue to forest health furthers a public purpose, i.e., long-term water management; a law dedicating the same revenue to necessary infrastructure improvements furthers a public use. The same can be said of water-positive development policies: a law requiring developers to invest, above and beyond their own impact, in long-term watershed health certainly furthers a public purpose.
Thus, Kelo spurred national concern that private land could be condemned for the vaguest of public purposes. Perhaps forecasting the likes of water-positive development regulations, property rights advocates went a step further, arguing that Kelo showed the Court’s willingness to allow regulatory takings to obliterate property rights as we knew them. In response, they turned to ballot measures. Notably, only Arizona’s Proposition 207 passed.
C. Takings and Eminent Domain in Arizona
Arizona has enshrined additional protections against eminent domain power in its constitution and by statute. Article 2, section 17 of the Arizona Constitution states that “[n]o private property shall be taken or damaged for public or private use without just compensation.” It further notes that “whether the contemplated use be really public shall be a judicial question,” decided without deference to the legislature. As with the Fifth Amendment Takings Clause, diminution in value alone is not a taking; a regulation must prevent a property from being used for any “economically viable” purpose to which the land is “reasonably adapted.” WND requirements—which oftentimes align with internal corporate interests—are unlikely to prevent semiconductor manufacturers like TSMC from using the property as intended.
Proposition 207, now the “Private Property Rights Protection Act,” aims to protect Arizona’s private property owners from partial regulatory takings, i.e., state and local regulations that diminish property value but fall short of outright condemnation. Under section 12-1134, a landowner is owed just compensation if three conditions are met. First, the regulation must be a “land use law” that was “enacted after the date the property is transferred to the owner.” Second, the law must reduce “the existing rights to use, divide, sell or possess private real property.” Third, and crucially, the law must reduce the property’s fair market value.
Section 12-1134 includes several exemptions, a few of which are relevant. It exempts laws that “[l]imit or prohibit” uses for public health and safety, including “health and sanitation” and “pollution control.” For example, laws requiring dustproof paving of certain parking lots and driveways are exempt as pollution control measures. Still, protecting health and safety must be the law’s “principal purpose”; “[m]ere declaration” is insufficient. It also exempts regulations that “[d]o not directly regulate an owner’s land.” In addition, section 12-1134 allows cities to request that landowners voluntarily waive any “Prop 207” rights, and developers that decline to do so may receive a negative recommendation from the city’s planning department.
Ultimately, section 12-1134 is unlikely to prevent WND requirements. Regulations that require semiconductor plants to optimize their on-site water use, i.e., avoidance, almost certainly increase the plant’s property value. In addition, regulations that address the water quality of plant discharge are safely within the public health and safety requirement. And because a land use law must “directly regulate” land, offsite measures, i.e., offset requirements, are also likely exempt.
IV. Planning for the Worst and Hoping for the Best
There is a clear legal basis for requiring semiconductor manufacturers, such as TSMC, to engage in water-neutral development. Most obviously, there are numerous requirements at the state and local levels in Arizona that already require developers to reduce their water impact. A scheme requiring new semiconductor plants to be water-neutral further survives any federal or state takings issues, including that of “Prop 207.”
Still, Arizona’s current statutory limitations on development fees prevent water-neutral development, and the WRAF program in particular, from reaching its full potential. Legislative change is necessary to allow WRAF revenue to finance nontraditional water resource projects. At the very least, the City of Phoenix should modify the WRAF credit program to allow developers to privately offset impact through investment in conservation projects. On the other hand, mandating water-positive development likely fails as an unconstitutional exaction that lacks an appropriate nexus. Still, state and local actors can enact policies that incentivize semiconductor companies to voluntarily pursue water-positive development.
A. Mandating Neutrality
The City of Phoenix should modify its existing WRAF program to better reflect a mitigation hierarchy approach to water management. First and foremost, it must allow for offsets that go beyond short-term augmentation. Unfortunately, statutory limits on development fees hamstring progress in this area. To be a true WND policy, WRAF needs to expand to fund and facilitate rehabilitation, infrastructure improvement, and conservation efforts.
Current takings law does not prevent regulations that mandate water-neutral development. As long as the fee remains proportional to impact, WRAF can—and should—be dedicated to offset strategies. If prior appropriation can be updated to recognize in-stream flows as a beneficial use not subject to forfeiture, then conservation efforts should be fairly seen, per statute, as a “beneficial use” that is “associated with providing necessary public services” to new, water-intensive development. It is merely a matter of being willing to consider long-term impact versus short-term impact.
The state legislature can make this change by expanding WRAF’s definition of “necessary public services” to include “water offset projects.” These projects should be defined broadly, allowing in-state investments in watershed and forest health, tribal infrastructure improvements, or reservoir storage. This change can be made while still requiring the City to partially shoulder infrastructure construction costs and fully pay operating costs. The City already has authority to distinguish between types of industrial uses, and thus, it could limit this broader reading to semiconductor manufacturers.
A more measured change would be expanding Phoenix City Ordinance section 30-5 to expressly credit developers, including semiconductor manufacturers, for in-state or in-basin offsets. This route sacrifices the benefits of a coordinated city-level approach to financing water management projects. Regardless, requiring semiconductor manufacturers to offset their water impact will provide a novel funding source for projects that are vital to Arizona’s long-term success but notoriously difficult to finance.
The credit system is ripe for change in other ways. Not all water is created equally, and credits for procuring water should reflect that. Chip manufacturing is important but does not warrant depleting Arizona’s groundwater. Thus, the City should offer a much-reduced groundwater credit that disincentivizes use of groundwater rights. Such a scheme will better internalize the long-term impact of groundwater depletion.
Last, the City needs to greatly increase transparency in its use of WRAF funds. Even without the modifications suggested here, WRAF reflects WND principles and should be advertised this way. Still, to best invest in long-term water security, the City must look beyond short-term augmentation. If the state legislature is unwilling to adapt, the City should encourage semiconductor manufacturers, which reside at the forefront of technology and efficiency, to do so instead.
B. Encouraging Positivity
While state or local governments cannot mandate water-positive development, they can readily develop incentive programs. For example, the state legislature could develop a property tax scheme that grants a credit or reduced tax rate to projects that demonstrate water-positive impact. Approved projects would be subject to an annual audit that would confirm ongoing compliance. At the local level, the City of Phoenix and other municipalities should consider developing an expedited permitting process for water-positive designs. In addition, the City of Phoenix should add water-positive development as a goal in its 2025 General Plan.
V. Conclusion
Together, these changes can make water-neutral development the new baseline for semiconductor manufacturers. Codifying best practices has the added benefit of heading off public concerns; in theory, an approved project will necessarily be a responsible water user. As the City explores more ambitious water-management strategies, semiconductor manufacturers are ideal test cases and partners. Armed with resources that most can only dream of, semiconductor manufacturers can help Phoenix become “the sustainable desert city.”