What are some of the unanswered questions around prison privatization?
Private prison firms are certainly taking steps to diversify beyond managing just prisons, jails, and detention centers. In fact, they have been reading the tea leaves for many years that individuals under some sort of correctional supervision in the community are growing while prison populations are very slowly starting to shrink. To remain financially sound, some of the largest private prison firms have bought companies that provide electronic monitoring services, residential treatment centers such as drug treatment facilities, and even transportation services such as companies that transport incarcerated individuals between courthouses and prisons and between different prison facilities.
Firms that mange prisons and detention centers have also gained a foothold in countries outside the United States. For example, England, Wales, and Australia house more than 18 percent of their prison population in private prisons. Some countries have also started to rethink the relationship between government corrections and private firms. Even though we have relied on the private sector to manage prisons for decades, our governments (state and federal) have never asked these corporations to reduce recidivism rates more than the government has been able to do. After I published Inside Private Prisons, I received a grant from the Pulitzer Center on Crisis Reporting to visit two relatively new private prisons: one in Australia and one in New Zealand, both of which operate within performance-based contracts. What this means for those contracts is that if private prison operators do better than government-run prisons at reducing recidivism, they receive an annual bonus. Is this replicable in America? Are there lessons learned from the experiments underway in Australia and New Zealand?
And in terms of unanswered questions, there are some critical gaps in the law around accountability, transparency, and constitutionality when it comes to the privatization of corrections. How much responsibility can governments delegate to private operators? For example, can private corrections officials issue disciplinary violations that could increase incarcerated individuals’ length of stay behind bars? Can private firms pay incarcerated workers and immigrant detainees far below minimum wage to perform work inside and outside their facilities? Are private firms required to comply with public information requests? Even if they do comply, what are they legally authorized to redact? Some of these issues are currently being litigated, but our country has never truly grappled with the myriad issues around how private prison firms operate in America.