I. Introduction
Boilerplate terms in contracts are “terms that are similar or identical in other agreements of a similar type.” Examples include choice-of-law clauses, forum selection clauses, damages limitations, and, of particular interest here, arbitration clauses. The commonly held view is that even in commercial contracts, boilerplate terms “are frequently pasted from prior deals: these are terms that no one reads, let alone bargains over.” As a result, while boilerplate terms are inexpensive to produce, they can lead to “errors that remain in the contract even in the face of adverse legal consequences.”
Stephen J. Choi, Mitu Gulati, and Robert E. Scott have identified several types of errors that can result from the use of boilerplate contract terms. Repetition in the use of a boilerplate term can result in “rote usage”—when “standardized terms . . . get used by rote so consistently that they lose a shared meaning and become a ritualized legal incantation”—and “encrustation”—when “the intelligibility of language deteriorates significantly as legal jargon is added to standard formulations, leading to linguistic variations of the same clause.” Eventually, a boilerplate term “can be emptied of any recoverable meaning” and become (in their parlance) a “contractual black hole.” Boilerplate terms that have become contractual black holes pose “a heightened risk that courts may be persuaded to adopt an interpretation of the term at issue that is antithetical to the functioning of the market that relies on the standard contract to regulate the rights and duties of the participating parties.”
Or the boilerplate terms can be “landmines”—“embedded language that lies dormant, sometimes for many years,” before “the harmful mutation is used as leverage in a subsequent dispute.” Contractual landmines can arise in a variety of circumstances. They can be “historic holdovers” that are “empty vessels” until “experienced litigators assert an unexpected meaning for the term.” They can be random errors that result when a drafter “inserts language that might have made sense in a different context . . . but is problematic” in the contract in which it is used. Or they can result when “a standardized, and well understood, term is changed by the intentional addition (or omission) of a new phrase or clause because of a conflict at the deal making stage that must be overcome to get the transaction done.” Regardless of the source, these “blunders, gaps, and booby traps in the documents do not diminish over time with repeated use; if anything, the general pattern is that the contracts develop more landmines over time.”
The paradigmatic case of contractual boilerplate studied by Choi, Gulati, and Scott is the pari passu clause in sovereign bond contracts. This clause, “a boilerplate formulation common to sovereign debt contracts for nearly 200 years,” continued to be included in such contracts by big firm lawyers long after courts interpreted the clause in a way that major players in the market agreed was incorrect and that imposed serious costs on the parties. The “lawyers had no incentive to revise the standard terms for their individual clients,” despite the fact that revision was in their clients’ collective interests.
But firms obtain contractual boilerplate not only from their lawyers, but also from a variety of third-party boilerplate providers. Thus, as stated by Lisa Bernstein, “[t]rade associations are, and traditionally have been, important sources of standard-form contracts—in the form of both traditional contracts and trading rules that can be incorporated into contracts by reference.” Examples include the American Institute of Architects, local realtors associations, and the trade associations of commodities firms studied by Bernstein. Form sellers, such as TruStage Compliance Solutions (formerly CUNA Mutual Group) with its financial services contracts for credit unions, sell standard form contracts, typically to smaller entities that do not want to pay lawyers to draft forms customized for them. The Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, in its study of consumer financial services arbitration, reported that “[a]t least 83 of the 141 small to mid-sized banks (58.9%) in the checking account sample used some version of a standard form prepared by a single form provider.” While some third-party boilerplate providers provide entire standard form contracts, others provide only specialized contract terms. The International Chamber of Commerce, for instance, publishes its Incoterms and Uniform Customs and Practice for Documentary Credits, among others, while arbitration institutions provide both model arbitration clauses and standard form arbitration rules.
This article examines whether contractual boilerplate from third-party boilerplate providers avoids the problems with contractual boilerplate identified by Choi, Gulati, and Scott, with a particular emphasis on arbitration institutions and arbitration boilerplate. The article first offers some general thoughts on contractual boilerplate and third-party boilerplate providers. Then it discusses arbitration institutions as third-party boilerplate providers. Finally, the article identifies possible examples of encrustation, contractual black holes, and contractual landmines in arbitration boilerplate. It concludes that third-party boilerplate providers do not avoid the problems identified by Choi, Gulati, and Scott, nor do they necessarily result in prompt correction of problems that do occur.
II. Third-Party Boilerplate Providers and Contractual Boilerplate
Third-party boilerplate providers differ in a variety of ways from the law firms studied by Choi, Gulati, and Scott as sources of contractual boilerplate. This part offers some preliminary thoughts on those differences and their possible implications for contractual boilerplate as analyzed by Choi, Gulati, and Scott. It focuses on three ways in which at least some third-party boilerplate providers differ from law firms that draft sovereign bond contracts: some third-party boilerplate providers (1) operate on a not-for-profit rather than a for-profit basis (“not-for-profit”); (2) create industry standard forms (“standardization”); and (3) specialize in particular types of boilerplate terms (“specialization”).
A. Not-for-Profit
Unlike law firms, some third-party boilerplate providers are not-for-profit entities. Kevin Davis has identified a number of differences between not-for-profit entities and for-profit entities as providers of boilerplate: not-for-profit entities may (1) “take into account benefits and costs that are not recognized by for-profit organizations”; (2) be “relatively well placed to stimulate demand for contracts by credibly assuring prospective users of their value”; (3) “produce contracts of a given quality at a relatively low cost because they have superior ability to attract volunteer labor”; and (4) “produce contracts at a relatively low cost because they enjoy preferential tax treatment.”
The extent to which the incentives facing not-for-profit entities, especially ones competing with for-profit entities in the marketplace, in fact differ or alter their behavior relative to for-profit entities is uncertain. Even if not-for-profit entities do take into account different costs and benefits from for-profit entities, it is not obvious whether that would make them more or less likely to provide problematic boilerplate. That said, the lower costs faced by not-for-profit entities producing contractual boilerplate might make it economical for them to produce greater documentation surrounding the boilerplate they provide, thus reducing the likelihood that a contractual black hole will form. Likewise, not-for-profit entities may have greater incentive to make public such documentation (perhaps to enhance their fundraising and other efforts), also reducing the likelihood that the original meaning will be lost. Conversely, not-for-profits might be slower to respond to the need for changes in their boilerplate (such as to address contractual black holes or landmines), either because of the differing incentives they face or their volunteer labor force. And to the extent the not-for-profit boilerplate provider has the characteristics of a private legislature, the drafting and revision process may face additional limitations and hurdles to overcome.
B. Standardization
Trade associations might provide boilerplate that serves as the de facto industry standard. If so, one certainly might still see rote reiteration of boilerplate but perhaps less encrustation (if nothing else because there will be fewer variations in contract language). To the extent the standardized boilerplate is provided by a trade association, the trade association might be likely to revisit and revise it on a regular basis (such that black holes and landmines might be less likely to persist):
These contracts and rules [provided by trade associations] were regularly revised in response to problems that arose, changes in technology, and other changes in market conditions. The process of adopting these changes was—and in the case of trading rules, continues to be—costly and time-consuming. . . . Changes are researched and debated extensively. In most groups, rule changes must be approved by a majority of group members, making it important for the revisers to clearly articulate the reasons for the proposed change. Although changes in optional standard-form contracts do not typically require membership approval, in practice associations go to great lengths to adopt only those changes that will be widely accepted in the trade.
So, like boilerplate provided by not-for-profits more generally, standardized boilerplate may be more likely to have its drafting history documented and to be revised regularly, albeit through an arduous and demanding process.
In addition, trade associations may provide an internal dispute resolution system under which disputes between members are resolved in arbitration with industry-expert arbitrators rather than in court. By keeping disputes between parties to standardized boilerplate out of the courts, trade association arbitration may reduce the likelihood that the meaning of contractual boilerplate will be lost or that landmines will appear because the arbitrators deciding any disputes will be “well versed in the meaning of trade rules and standard contract provisions” (even if the arbitrators apply those rules formalistically rather than flexibly).
C. Specialization
Some third-party boilerplate providers provide standard form contracts in their entirety. Others provide individual terms as to which they have particular expertise, which parties and their lawyers can incorporate (either word-for-word or by reference) into their standard form contracts.
Specialization would seem to reduce the likelihood that boilerplate would lose its meaning or result in contractual landmines. First, specialization might mean that the provider has fewer contractual terms to draft in the first instance and hence to monitor on an ongoing basis. The lower ongoing cost of monitoring and updating specialized boilerplate makes it easier to retain knowledge of the meaning of the boilerplate terms and avoid landmines. It also might enable the specialized boilerplate provider to identify court interpretations that require the meaning of boilerplate terms to be clarified. Second, specialization is likely to result from and lead to greater expertise in a particular type of term. The greater expertise of specialized third-party boilerplate providers likewise should make them better able both to retain information about the meaning of boilerplate terms and to recognize the need for clarification. Accordingly, boilerplate provided by specialized providers seems less likely to result in contractual black holes and landmines and more likely to be revised in response to an aberrant court interpretation.
III. Arbitration Boilerplate and Third-Party Boilerplate Providers
This part looks at arbitration institutions as a type of third-party boilerplate provider. It first provides a brief introduction to arbitration and discusses arbitration clauses as an example of contractual boilerplate. It then describes the role of arbitration institutions as third-party providers of arbitration boilerplate.
A. Arbitration Clauses as Contractual Boilerplate
Arbitration is a common albeit not ubiquitous form of dispute resolution: the use of arbitration clauses varies by industry and by size of firm within an industry. By agreeing to arbitrate, parties agree to have their disputes resolved by private judges (arbitrators) rather than in the public court system. As often stated by the U.S. Supreme Court, arbitration is “a matter of contract”: parties cannot be required to arbitrate if they have not agreed to do so. Stated otherwise, court litigation is the default means of resolving disputes. Parties can contract out of that default rule by agreeing to arbitration.
An arbitration clause is a classic example of a boilerplate contract provision. Parties typically agree to arbitration before a dispute arises by including a (pre-dispute) arbitration clause in their contract. In negotiated contracts, the negotiation and drafting of arbitration clauses appears to track the story of commercial boilerplate production more generally, as told by Choi, Gulati, and Scott. Arbitration clauses (like other boilerplate terms such as choice-of-law clauses)
are often added at the last minute and addressed at the end of contract negotiations with very little thought and consideration given to the consequences and intricacies of the clause, hence earning the name “midnight” clause. The excuse for this late consideration by some is fear that negotiations will break down by damaging the optimistic structuring of a deal by introducing the idea that something might go wrong.
Because of the tight timeframe, rather than being drafted from scratch, often “boilerplate language from another unrelated contract is lifted and inserted in the deal contract.” As a result, commentators conclude, “poorly drafted dispute resolution clauses frequently trap parties in a less than optimal dispute resolution process.” By comparison, arbitration clauses (and other boilerplate terms) in standard form contracts presumably are not produced by the same last-minute negotiation and drafting process. Nonetheless, those clauses can be less than optimal as well.
B. Arbitration Institutions as Third-Party Boilerplate Providers
Although not required to do so, parties commonly agree to have an arbitration institution administer any arbitration that might occur. Thus, 89.5 percent of a sample of arbitration clauses in international supply contracts (77 out of 86) provided for institutional (rather than ad hoc) arbitration, with the American Arbitration Association (AAA) (or its international wing, the International Centre for Dispute Resolution (ICDR)) and the International Chamber of Commerce (ICC) International Court of Arbitration the most commonly chosen institutions. Essentially all U.S. consumer financial service contracts with an arbitration clause likewise provided for an administering institution, almost always either the AAA or JAMS.
Arbitration institutions provide administrative services to parties during the course of the arbitration proceeding. The arbitration institution may act as a court clerk’s office, accepting and distributing filings made in the arbitration, scheduling hearings, and the like. It can serve as the appointing authority, appointing arbitrators when a party fails to do so and ruling on challenges to arbitrators. It may also handle the fees charged to the parties both for its services and for the arbitrators’ services.
But arbitration institutions also serve as third-party boilerplate providers for parties who use their services. First, institutions draft and publish model arbitration clauses that parties can include in their contracts. Use of the model clauses is not mandatory, and, as noted below, parties rarely use the model clause without modification. Increasingly, institutions go beyond simply providing a model arbitration clause and sometimes provide an online tool to assist parties in drafting a more customized arbitration clause.
Second, institutions provide a bundle of standard form arbitration rules that parties can incorporate by reference into their arbitration agreement. Indeed, the rules commonly provide that by agreeing to have an institution administer their arbitration the parties also agree to be subject to the institution’s arbitration rules. Arbitration institutions often enlist both internal and external expertise (e.g., from users of the institution’s arbitration services, arbitration practitioners, and arbitrators) to prepare and revise their arbitration rules, albeit typically with less public involvement than, say, the process for revising federal court rules. Institutional arbitration rules cover the full extent of the arbitration proceeding, from the filing of the claim to the issuance of the award. With some exceptions, the parties are free to—and commonly do—modify various of the institutional rules.
In a minority of cases, parties to arbitration agreements do not specify an arbitration institution but instead agree to have the arbitration proceed on an ad hoc basis—i.e., with the arbitrators themselves handling the administrative services and with some other third party (or court) serving as appointing authority. In such cases, the parties can either draft arbitration rules themselves or agree to a set of arbitration rules created for use in ad hoc proceedings. An example of the latter is the UNCITRAL Arbitration Rules, which were promulgated in 1976 (and amended in 2010 and 2013) by the United Nations Commission on International Trade Law (UNCITRAL). The UNCITRAL Arbitration Rules have a well-documented drafting history and have influenced the development of institutional arbitration rules.
Arbitration institutions reflect several (although not all) of the characteristics of third-party boilerplate providers discussed in Part II. Arbitration institutions are both for-profit (e.g., JAMS) and not-for-profit (e.g., AAA) entities. Each institution focuses on a single, specialized type of boilerplate—arbitration clauses and rules. Arbitration boilerplate is not standardized, however. No single arbitration institution has a sufficient market share to impose a standardized arbitration clause, and the costs of modifying model arbitration clauses and institutional arbitration rules in contracts evidently is low enough that parties do so with some frequency.
IV. Arbitration Boilerplate and the Theory of Contractual Boilerplate
This part considers whether the problems with contractual boilerplate identified by Choi, Gulati, and Scott occur in arbitration boilerplate, despite (or perhaps because of ) the involvement of third-party boilerplate providers (arbitration institutions). Its analysis is anecdotal, rather than empirical. Nonetheless, it provides evidence that, at a minimum, third-party boilerplate providers do not avoid the problems with contractual boilerplate that Choi, Gulati, and Scott identify.
This part first examines scope provisions, which define the set of disputes the parties have agreed to arbitrate, as an example of rote usage and encrustation of contract language. Second, it discusses whether institutional arbitration rules providing that arbitrators have authority to resolve challenges to their own jurisdiction, when interpreted as a delegation clause, constitute a contractual black hole. Third, it looks at several types of arbitration boilerplate that are, or might be, landmines.
A. Scope Provisions and Encrustation
An arbitration clause must define the set of disputes that the parties are agreeing to submit to arbitration—i.e., its scope. Whether a dispute falls within the scope of an arbitration clause is a commonly litigated issue in disputes over the enforceability of arbitration clauses. Parties wishing to avoid arbitration argue that the dispute is outside the scope of the clause and thus must be decided in court, while parties wishing to arbitrate argue the opposite.
Although arbitration institutions commonly offer model arbitration clauses for parties to incorporate into their contracts, those model clauses vary in how they define the scope of the obligation to arbitrate, as shown in Table 1. The AAA clause, for example, applies to “[a]ny controversy or claim,” while the ICC clause applies to “[a]ll disputes” and the JAMS clauses apply to “[a]ny dispute, claim or controversy” (for domestic contracts) and “[a]ny dispute, controversy or claim” (for international disputes). The language in the JAMS clause for international disputes is the same as in the UNCITRAL clause. The AAA clause, as well as the JAMS and UNCITRAL clauses, use the connecting phrase “arising out of or relating to,” while the ICC clause uses the connecting phrase “arising out of or in connection with.” The ICC clause then concludes with “the present contract.” The AAA clause adds “or the breach thereof,” the UNCITRAL clause adds “or the breach, termination or invalidity thereof,” and the JAMS clauses add “or the breach, termination, enforcement, interpretation or validity thereof, including the determination of the scope or applicability of this agreement to arbitrate” or “including the formation, interpretation, breach or termination thereof, including whether the claims asserted are arbitrable.” All of the model clauses aim to include a broad range of disputes within their scope. Despite the wording differences, there is no indication that any model clause seeks to cover a different set of disputes than the others.
Moreover, parties rarely follow the model clauses, even as to such core provisions as scope. For example, in a sample of eighty-six international supply contracts with arbitration clauses, only nine of the clauses (or 10.5 percent) included language matching one of the model clauses quoted in Table 1. Prior studies have similar findings.