Reducing the threshold for a presumption of anticompetitive effects
Guideline 1 lowers the threshold for determining when a transaction results in a “highly concentrated market” to the level used by the guidelines issued in the 1980s and 1990s. Guideline 1 describes the use of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (“HHI”) to calculate market concentration. The HHI sums the squares of the market share of each competitor in the market. Under the 2010 merger guidelines, “[b]ased on their experience, the Agencies classif[ied] markets” with an HHI over 2,500 as “highly concentrated.” Transactions resulting in highly concentrated markets that involved an increase of more than 200 points were presumed to be likely to enhance market power.
Pursuant to draft Guideline 1, the agencies not only reduce the standard for a “highly concentrated” HHI to 1,800 from 2,500, but they also reduce the level of the post-transaction delta from 200 to 100. Accordingly, mergers in markets with HHIs greater than 1,800 and an increase of greater than 100 “cause[] undue concentration and trigger[] a structural presumption that the merger[s] may substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly.”
Another change is the addition of the “structural presumption” that mergers leading to a market share in excess of 30 percent are illegal.
Creating a dominance concept under U.S. law
Dominance is not a concept enshrined in U.S. antitrust law, but it has been a part of merger analysis in Europe. Guideline 7 seeks to discourage any transaction that makes it harder for remaining competitors to compete. The guideline suggests a firm could be treated as “dominant” with a market share as low as 30 percent and also indicates that transactions that might increase switching costs, interfere with use of competitive alternatives, deprive rivals of economies of scale, eliminate a nascent competitive threat, or “in any other way” entrench the combined firm’s position could be challenged. The agencies will view any merger involving a dominant firm with intense scrutiny.
Focus on mergers that “further a trend” towards market concentration
Guideline 8 declares that the agencies will now scrutinize mergers in markets that have been trending toward concentrated, and thereby the proposed transaction may substantially lessen competition. The guideline sets forth two factors to establish this trend: (1) if a market has shown a history of consolidation, such as a market with an HHI exceeding 1,000 and approaching 1,800, or (2) if the merger would increase the rate of concentration, such as increases in HHI over 200.
Adding examination of serial acquisitions as a whole
Guideline 9 notes that the agencies have created another pathway to target mergers that might, in the past, have evaded agency scrutiny: challenging a pending transaction based on past lawfully consummated mergers and company documents reflecting a strategy of growth through acquisition. Specifically, if either of the parties has a pattern or strategy of consolidation through acquisition, the agencies will examine the impact of the cumulative strategy to determine if that strategy may substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly. If the agencies find that the strategy or acquisition history of a firm is suspect, they may combine multiple acquisitions for the purposes of their analysis of other indicia of lessening competition. Many interpret Guideline 9 as a reflection of skepticism of private equity transactions.
Suggesting increased enforcement of mergers involving multi-sided platforms
In another warning shot at the tech industry, the agencies made clear in Guideline 10 that anticompetitive effects on a single platform may make a merger illegal. The agencies view such platforms as markets themselves and platform operators as having conflicts of interest to the extent they use their platform to sell products. Thus, a merger between a platform operator and a seller of goods who uses the platform will attract the attention of the agencies even if the merger would be totally innocuous if viewed only in the market of the products sold by the acquired seller.
Considering impacts on labor markets
Guideline 11 confirms that the agencies will consider labor markets as they would other supply markets in analyzing mergers, where employers are competing buyers for labor. When assessing the degree to which the merging firms compete for labor, the agencies will consider whether the merger may result in lower wages or slowed wage growth, worse benefits or working conditions, or any other degradation of workplace quality.
Market definition: Considering bundling
The agencies stated in an appendix detailing how they define markets that they will consider bundled products in a single relevant market, even if such conduct would not violate Section 2 of the Sherman Act. Bundling is conditioning the sale of a product in one market on the sale of a product in another market, or otherwise linking the sales of two products. By considering bundled products together, the agencies may be able to find that firms exceed the thresholds described above based on control of products outside the market directly affected by the transaction.
Efficiencies: Relegated to the appendix
While the current guidelines give an explanation of how efficiencies may “enhance the merged firm’s ability and incentive to compete, which may result in lower prices” and other consumer benefits, the proposed guidelines are less clear on the impact of efficiencies to the agencies’ analysis. The relevant section (IV.3.) begins with a quote from United States v. Philadelphia Nat’l Bank that “possible economies [from a merger] cannot be used as a defense to illegality.” 374 U.S. 321, 371 (1963). It goes on to identify certain “cognizable efficiencies” which “must be of sufficient magnitude and likelihood” to “prevent the creation of a monopoly.”