Even if the implementer were to expect that after litigation expenses, a court may land on an adjudicated royalty rate that is closer to the intrinsic economic value of the patented technology (say, $5 per unit) or even a $3 per unit FRAND rate based on a pre-standardization “bottom-up” evaluation under the hypothetical negotiation setting, the free-market royalty rate the implementer is willing to pay would still be sufficiently above these rates, due to the elimination of commercially feasible alternatives after the standardization, high litigation expenses, and loss of profit and other costs due to injunctions, etc. Thus, the post-standardization free-market royalty rate would still be supra-FRAND, with the difference between the free-market and real-FRAND royalty rates, i.e., the hold-up value, varying across implementers according to each implementer’s profit margin and willingness to pay.
Price discrimination and SEP licensing patterns in practice
It is important to note that unlike in a competitive market where the licensor would be willing to set the royalty rate equal to the licensor’s marginal cost, the lock-in nature of standards and the risk of injunctions provides the licensor with significant market power, which enables the licensor to price discriminate—maximizing its profit by varying the royalty rate charged for each individual licensee based on the expected willingness to pay of each licensee.
In economic terms, there are three prerequisites for price discrimination: the licensor possesses substantial market power; has the ability to identify or estimate differences in willingness to pay among licensees; and can prevent the resale of the license, i.e., arbitrage. All of these conditions can generally be met in an SEP licensing negotiation. First, SEP holders have substantial market power from each of their SEPs that are truly essential—there is no commercially feasible alternative for the implementer to comply with the industry standard. Second, SEP holders are oftentimes able to estimate the potential licensees’ profit margins, exposure to injunctions, and litigation costs, and thus the potential licensees’ willingness to pay based on public information, such as the licensees’ own financial reports and industry analyses and data published by third parties, combined with their own industry knowledge. Third, SEP licensing agreements often include clauses that restrict resale of the license to other parties, which prevents arbitrage and maintains price discrimination.
The general trends in SEP licensing practices in the real world are consistent with the theoretical framework of hold-up discussed above. There is evidence that SEP holders strategically sequence their licensing and litigation efforts to exploit the implementers’ varied profit margins and willingness to pay, and maximize their profits by extracting differential hold-up values from the implementers. To be more specific, SEP holders typically structure their licensing and litigation efforts as follows.
SEP holders may first target major manufacturers with relatively high profit margins, such as Apple and Samsung in the mobile device industry, utilizing injunction threats, to arrive at free-market license agreements with high per-unit royalty rates and significant amounts of royalties. These manufacturers tend to face significant amounts of potential profit loss from injunctions, including loss from short-term sales bans and long-term market trust issues among business partners and end consumers, which combined with relatively high profit margins drive up their willingness to pay. Therefore, the SEP holders may be able to reach free-market license agreements with this type of licensees at high per-unit royalty rates, extracting high hold-up values and obtaining significant amounts of royalties.
After the SEP holders successfully obtain license agreements containing high per-unit royalty rates from the previous step, they may use these licenses as “comparable benchmarks” and approach major manufacturers with relatively low profit margins, such as OPPO, vivo, and Xiaomi in the mobile device industry. Since these manufacturers have lower profit margins and therefore lower maximum-attainable willingness to pay, their per-unit royalty rates are generally lower than those of licensees with higher profit margins. But their high exposure to injunctions can still mean that those lower per-unit rates represent a large proportion of their profit margins. Hold-up can therefore still result in excessive per-unit royalty rates compared to truly FRAND royalty rates.
Below are a few examples of SEP holders securing license agreements with major manufacturers who have relatively high profit margins first, and then with those who have relatively low profits margins, based on public information:
- InterDigital, a major cellular standard SEP holder, first secured licenses with major mobile device manufacturers who had relatively high profit margins—Apple in 2016 and Samsung in 2014, before aggressively targeting major mobile device manufactures with lower profit margins, such as Xiaomi (with litigation started in 2020 and license agreement reached in 2021), OPPO (with litigation started in 2021 and in the process of litigation now), TCL (with license agreement reached in 2023), and Lenovo (with litigation started in 2019 and in the process of litigation now).
- The licensing and litigation history of ZTE, who is another major cellular standard SEP holder, demonstrates a similar pattern. According to public information, ZTE secured licenses or initiated litigations against major mobile device manufacturers who had relatively high profit margins first—Apple (license agreement signed in 2020) and Samsung (license agreement signed in 2021 followed by litigation brought by a related party G+ in 2024), before approaching major mobile device manufacturers with lower profit margins, such as Tinno (patent dispute litigation started in 2021), vivo (cross-license agreement signed in 2024), and OPPO (patent dispute litigation started in 2022 and settlement reached in 2024).
- In earlier years, Nokia secured license agreements with major mobile device manufacturers at the time—Research In Motion (“RIM”, the manufacturer of BlackBerry), Apple, and Samsung—who had relatively high profit margins. After that, Nokia reached license agreements with major mobile device manufacturers that had lower profit margins, such as with Xiaomi and Huawei in 2017, with OPPO in 2018, and with vivo in 2019. It appears that upon the roll-out of 5G technology, Nokia started another round of licensing negotiations with major manufacturers, including Samsung, Apple, OPPO, and vivo.
Due to the lack of publicly available information regarding license term details, a comprehensive and precise quantitative evaluation cannot be performed to calculate and compare the royalty rates each licensor imposed across different licenses, or to assess the extent to which hold-up value is embedded in the agreed-upon royalties. Nevertheless, for demonstration purposes, it can be roughly estimated, for example, that the per unit royalty rate Nokia charged to Apple, an implementer who has a relatively high profit margin, is about twice that of OPPO, an implementer who has a much lower profit margin. This is consistent with the theoretical framework of hold-up discussed above, indicating that SEP holders have pricing power in the licensing market and thus are able to extract differentiated royalties from implementers based on their profit margins and willingness to pay.
Notably, Nokia was able to extract a relatively high portion of the profit margins as royalties from manufacturers like OPPO—while the average per-unit profit margin of OPPO, vivo, and Xiaomi is less than 3% of Apple’s per-unit profit margin, the per-unit royalty rate paid by OPPO is about half of that paid by Apple. On average, then, OPPO, vivo, and Xiaomi paid roughly seventeen-times as much as Apple in royalties as a proportion of their profit margin. This suggests that low profit margin manufacturers may have been even more held-up by SEP holders, paying even higher portions of their profit margins as royalties.
Conclusion
Licenses established through “free market” negotiations between SEP holders and implementers are inherently influenced by the lock-in effect induced by standardization, further compounded by the threat of injunctions. Consequently, these agreements may entail a range of supra-FRAND royalty rates that reflect varied hold-up values. To the extent that these licenses are used as comparable licenses in subsequent license negotiations or court rulings, royalties calculated based on such comparable licenses would exceed the intrinsic value of the patented technology, exacerbating the issue of hold-up. Thus, it is crucial for the negotiating parties and courts to recognize the possibility that comparable licenses are affected by hold-up and adjust accordingly in determining FRAND royalties. For example, consider that comparable licenses that could be used as a benchmark may be at a range of royalty rate, using the lowest rather than the average or median royalty rate among them is less likely to reflect the impact of hold-up. Evaluating the patent-at-issue based on a pre-standardization “bottom-up” approach under a hypothetical negotiation setting would also yield a royalty measure that is more consistent with the FRAND principle.