Simple statistics can be applied to these data as well, such as a correlation of pizza prices and soda quantity. For example, the correlation between pizza prices and soda quantity associated with Figure 2 is approximately -0.8. Here, a hypothetical merger of pizza and soda manufacturers could internalize an incentive to reduce the price of pizza to increase demand for soda.
Data on consumers’ individual consumption decisions can be used to gain a deeper understanding of the demand relationship between two products. For example, customers often will consume complementary products together, while products that are rarely consumed together are more likely to be substitutes or independent in demand.
Although the observed relationships between the two variables described above are a useful starting point, quantitative inferences based on such relationships may be misleading as consumer purchase decisions often are affected by other factors such as consumers’ incomes or the prices of other products. That is, antitrust agencies might look at the graph above and suggest that there may be other factors explaining why pizza prices might be lower in areas with greater soda consumption, i.e., there is no causal relationship between the two. Showing that the two change together over time would be helpful in responding. However, to help confirm our pizza/soda merger would result in incentives to lower prices, quantitative estimates of the influence of the price that one product has on the demand for another can be obtained through more sophisticated econometric techniques that account for additional factors that also potentially affect product demand. Regression analysis is one commonly used econometric tool that addresses such challenges by including measures of other factors in the same estimation equation that relates two variables of interest. For example, a regression equation might measure the change in soda demand following a change in the price of pizza, while also accounting for the price of soda and the consumer’s income.
More generally, regression analysis can be used to estimate the extent to which products are substitutes or complements for one another—e.g., regressions can be used to estimate diversion ratios between products. Diversion ratios are useful for thinking about both substitutes and complements, and have similar, but inverse, interpretations. With substitute products A and B, the diversion ratio from product A to product B measures the proportion of product A’s lost sales that flow to product B following a price increase on product A. With complementary products C and D, the diversion ratio from product C to product D is a negative number measuring the proportion of product C’s sales that also are lost by product D following an increase in the price of product C.
Economists frequently rely on diversion ratios as an input into models that predict merger price effects. For example, upward pricing pressure (“UPP”) indexes combine diversion ratios with price cost margins to generate predictions of the relative magnitude of a merger’s likely price effects. In the case of multiproduct firms that sell mixes of substitutes and complements, one can use diversion ratios among products to calculate a “generalized pricing pressure” (“GePP”) index. This index provides an overall measure of the likely direction and relative magnitude of the price effect of the merger that incorporates the incentives created by both substitute and complementary products.
With sufficient time and data, economists can estimate the price effects of multiproduct mergers more precisely by using sophisticated structural modeling techniques. Structural models require the economist to apply “structure” to data by designing a specific economic model, the parameters of which can be estimated using available data. For example, an economist may design a specific demand relationship between several products and estimate the parameters of that demand system. The estimated model of the demand relationship between products can then be used to simulate the effects of a proposed merger.
It is worth noting that although textbook examples of complements typically involve pairs of products, complementary effects may be generated by relationships among several products. For example, demand for soda and grated parmesan cheese may increase as the price of pizza falls. In such cases, it is important that the merger analysis consider the overall competitive effects of all interrelated products (i.e., complements and substitutes).
Complementarity as a Procompetitive Effect Distinct from Efficiency
Complementarity is properly viewed as a procompetitive effect, as opposed to a merger efficiency. Merger efficiencies decrease the incremental costs associated with making a product or, equivalently, improve product quality. Lower costs or improved quality increase the value of incremental sales to the merged firm, causing lower prices and/or increased output. By contrast, complementarity creates an incentive to decrease prices that is independent of any changes in incremental costs. That is, with a merger of complements, the merged entity can gain incremental sales on product B by lowering the price of product A, creating an incentive to decrease the price of product A that is independent of the cost of producing product A. Thus, even if our pizza/soda merger results in no cognizable merger efficiencies, it could still result in lower prices because of the incentives created by mergers of complements.
Evaluation of merger efficiencies can be, and often is, considered as an independent offset to any UPP that is associated with a proposed merger. In contrast, complementarity properly should be considered along with other changes in pricing incentives caused by the demand relationships between merging parties’ products.
Ignoring complementarity among products in the assessment of merger price effects can lead to erroneous conclusions about a transaction’s overall competitive effect. Consider the following example: Firm 1, which produces goods A, B, and Z, proposes to merge with Firm 2, which produces good C. Products A, B, and C are substitutes for one another, while product Z is a complement to the other three.
An antitrust agency can make two mistakes by ignoring the complementarity between product Z and the other three products.
First, if the agency focuses only on the substitute products involved in the transaction, it may conclude that the merger creates an incentive to raise prices that is too large to be offset by merger efficiencies. However, once the role of product Z is considered, any incentive to raise prices on substitute goods A, B, and C may be overwhelmed by incentives to lower prices to generate demand for complementary product Z. In this case, ignoring the role of product Z may cause a procompetitive merger to be blocked.
Second, by ignoring product B’s complementarity with product Z, the agency may determine that a divestiture of product B is warranted. In this case, there will be some benefits stemming from the consummated merger because of the complementarity between product Z, and products A and C. However, if product B is divested to a firm that does not own a complementary product, the divestiture buyer may have an incentive to increase the price of B, resulting in the divestiture inadvertently causing harm to consumers.
Complementarity as an Inextricably-Linked Procompetitive Effect as Opposed
to an Incognizable Out-of-Market Efficiency
Depending on the particular facts, the downward-pricing pressure of complementarity can materialize in the same market as the merging substitute products, as was described above, and/or in a separate market of the non-overlapping complement. Suppose that the downward-pricing pressure is predicted to occur outside the market of the substitute products and is predicted to be greater than the UPP predicted from merging substitute products. How should the antitrust agencies evaluate such a merger?
In general, the antitrust agencies take the position that an anticompetitive effect in one market cannot be offset by efficiencies in a different market, even if those “out-of-market” efficiencies are predicted to be greater than the harm. The 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines do, however, contain an exception in the case of “inextricably linked” efficiencies. The antitrust agencies may use their prosecutorial discretion to consider efficiencies that are not “strictly in the relevant market” but where they are “so inextricably linked” with the relevant market that a remedy in the relevant market would sacrifice the out-of-market efficiencies. Setting aside for the moment the question of whether the procompetitive effects of complementarity are a type of “efficiency,” inherently, those procompetitive effects are inextricably linked to the relevant market in which the merging parties’ products are substitutes. The downward-pricing pressure from merging complementary products requires the joint ownership of the complementary products to fully internalize the positive externality.
As explained above, complementarity should be analyzed as a procompetitive effect rather than a merger efficiency. The 2020 Vertical Merger Guidelines refer to EDM and complementarity in a section titled “Procompetitive Effects.” The 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines’ discussion of out-of-market efficiencies should not apply. Nonetheless, whether complementarity is categorized as a procompetitive effect or a merger efficiency, the agencies are likely to consider whether the effect is in the same market as the merging substitutes and apply the “out-of-market” framework from footnote 14 of the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines. Even under that rubric, the procompetitive effects of merging complements should be credited as inextricably linked even when the downward-pricing pressure is predicted to occur “out of market.” The procompetitive effect of complementarity in one market is inherently due to the merging with a product in another market. In other words, a remedy in a market with predicted anticompetitive effects would necessarily reduce the procompetitive effect in the complementary market. Agencies should use their prosecutorial discretion to maximize overall welfare in this situation by crediting the inextricably-linked procompetitive effect of complementarity.
Practical Pointers
As acquisitions involving complementary products become more common, considering the competitive effects of complementarity could be increasingly important. From an agency advocacy standpoint, therefore, it is critical to consider the kinds of evidence agency staff are likely to find most persuasive. Agencies evaluating this argument will find it most credible if it is reflected in and supported by evidence from multiple sources.
First, to the extent both merging parties’ ordinary course documents reflect the complementarity of products contemplated by the deal, the greater credibility the procompetitive benefits will have. For example, if a peanut butter manufacturer’s pre-deal strategic plans discuss the effects of jelly prices on demand for their peanut butter products, that reduces the likelihood that—in agency staff’s view—the complementarity story was simply “made for the deal.”
Second, just as importantly, company documents discussing or analyzing the transaction should reflect the importance of complementarity to the deal. For example, if the downward pricing incentives of complementarity are reflected in modeling for the combined company’s sales and margins, that lends credence to the claim that once the deal is closed, the combined company will have strong incentives to use the EDM from complementarity to be even more competitive, which will benefit customers. Ideally, the company’s deal analyses should reflect negative cross elasticity, i.e., a decrease in price of one product leads to increased demand for the other product. Moreover, it is also important to keep in mind that the term “complementary” can have very different meanings to business teams and economists. So, it is critical for internal business teams working on the deal to understand that economic complementarity is not the same as the business use of the term to simply mean non-overlapping—and rigorous use of the term in the economic sense will be most persuasive to agency staff.
Counsel should tailor guidance to clients to account for this fact, particularly in identifying ordinary course evidence to support the deal. For example, a request for or search of company documents for generic terms like “complements” or “complementarity” may not yield useful results because the business team uses those terms broadly. Rather, counsel should seek out evidence that is specific to the industry and the complementary products or services in the deal. In the case of a merger between peanut butter and jelly manufacturers, requests to the company for documents reflecting customer interest in purchasing both products together (e.g., customer X wants “one-stop shopping for peanut butter and jelly”) or sales teams tracking jelly pricing to assess demand for and pricing of peanut butter (or vice versa) are more likely to surface ordinary course materials that bolster and add credibility to the argument before agency staff. Direct engagement with internal sales or marketing teams may be needed to reach bedrock on the types of documents—e.g., emails with customers, strategic plans, or monthly sales updates—that exist in company files.
And third, quantitative evidence of complementarity and deal-specific incremental incentives to lower prices should be developed before engagement with agency staff. Having an economist prepare an analysis as discussed above in advance of filing will help staff get up to speed quickly and accelerate their understanding—and pressure testing—of the parties’ claims.
Conclusion
Complementarity is an important economic concept and has significant antitrust implications. Failing to analyze the procompetitive effects of merging complementary products can lead to erroneous enforcement decisions, reducing consumer welfare. Multiproduct firms merging complementary products should make sure to include arguments and evidence of the procompetitive effects of complementarity in their advocacy. In turn, the antitrust agencies should carefully consider complementarity and recognize that failing to do so could result in falsely condemning a procompetitive or benign merger.