Divestitures have other shortcomings. Even where they are effective in removing or reducing the anticompetitive effect, they often also undermine the procompetitive rationale for the deal. For example, a grocery merger might lower local inventory costs, a benefit that is undermined by requiring divestitures in overlapping geographic markets.
The inadequacy of existing remedial tools is a well-recognized problem with important consequences. When effective divestiture is not feasible, antitrust authorities confront the all-or-nothing dilemma of approval or denial. The Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission have brought major enforcement actions to block challenges in industries where effective divestiture was infeasible, typically (though not invariably) resulting in an abandonment or failure of the transaction. Other transactions are not even attempted because there is no workable divestiture strategy. As a consequence, potentially important efficiencies are never achieved. In still other mergers, antitrust authorities have chosen to accept the bitter (some upward price pressure) alongside the sweet (procompetitive benefits) and allow potentially harmful mergers to proceed. In all of these instances we ought to prefer an alternative that achieves the potential efficiency benefits with less public harm.
In this article, we propose the use of an alternative remedy: for the merged firm to take negative ownership positions in its remaining rivals. The simplest form of negative ownership is for the firm to take a short position. For example, as a condition for JetBlue’s merger with Spirit, the combined firm might be obliged to take a short position in American, United, and Delta Airlines.
The negative ownership remedy does not require taking a short position. As we explain, there are various ways to implement the remedy. For example, the managers of a merged JetBlue/Spirit might have been required, as a precondition of merger approval, to be paid under a new compensation scheme keyed to the merged firm’s performance relative to that of its major rivals. Negative ownership can alternatively be implemented through the sale of derivatives or bespoke contracts that have other attractive features, alongside serious implementation challenges, as we explore in greater detail below.
The negative ownership approach represents a different kind of divestiture. Instead of requiring merging firms to divest themselves of their interest in overlapping assets, our proposal would require merging firms to divest themselves of what would otherwise be an economic interest in raising their profits in a manner that also increases the profits of their unmerged rivals. Instead of requiring long selling of certain assets, our proposal would require short selling of other assets.
Continue reading the full text of this article in PDF format.