Competition and international trade policies are both potential sources of efficiency in the economy. It could be argued that, in an ideal world with no impediments to domestic and international trade and full mobility of inputs, products, and services, free trade would be the main source of market competition and efficiency that would allow countries to specialize in those sectors where they have comparative advantage. In this ideal world, free trade would be the main instrument of competition policy.
Nevertheless, in the real world, maintaining free international trade can present significant challenges. As soon as less than full mobility of inputs and products, market imperfections, regulatory distortions, and economies of scale are introduced, there is a need for competition policy and enforcement to complement international trade policy. Also, markets of different products may be highly related to one another, even though they are extremely different from each other. This inherent network of relationships creates the necessity of intervening in certain markets to offset issues arising in other related markets.
Services, for example, are important internationally non-tradable sectors that interact with the rest of the economy because they are key inputs with horizontal and vertical impact for the rest of economic activities. They are usually non-tradable in international markets, mainly explained by the existence of regulatory barriers of different types. Service sectors, like telecommunications, transport in different modalities, financial services, and energy normally present highly concentrated market structures because they have important network and scale economies, and in many cases they manage essential facilities so they require regulatory frameworks based on procompetitive principles and sound competition law enforcement to avoid private incentives to diminish competition. In this situation, an open international trade policy is not the only instrument to promote market efficiency. Trade policy can allow just a few players in the market; therefore, there is also a need for domestic competition policy and enforcement to increase effectiveness in service markets. Both instruments, competition policy and international trade policy, can thus become complementary to promote economic efficiency, growth, and economic development. The balance between both policies would depend on the specific needs of each market, considering product characteristics and the particular features of the country or region were such a market is present.
Competition law enforcement concentrates on the elimination of private incentives to restrain competition through anticompetitive unilateral conduct, market cartelization, and merger control, while international trade policy focuses mostly on the elimination of regulatory restraints and governmental decisions to regulate international trade flows. Given that both policies, international trade and competition, are complementary, the question that follows is how both policies should be coordinated, especially in a world of increasing global interconnection of jurisdictions that have different approaches to these matters.