Can shareholders act in ways that interfere with competition in the product markets of firms whose shares they own? Are shareholders that own shares of competitors (“common shareholders”) better able or more likely to do so than shareholders that own shares in only one competitor (“non-common share- holders”)? If so, how? What are the channels through which shareholders transmit anticompetitive signals? Can shareholders increase the likelihood of anticompetitive coordination between competitors by facilitating the detection and punishment of cheating? Are common or non-common shareholders more or less dangerous? Should antitrust law address these problems and, if so, how?
In this article, we explore a variety of factual scenarios that potentially raise significant antitrust issues from both an economic and a legal perspective. Although we do not believe that a case has been made that common owner- ship has systemic anticompetitive effects, as some have argued, we do believe that in particular factual contexts shareholders (common and non-common) can behave in ways that cause the firms in which they have an ownership interest to act anticompetitively. When they do, antitrust enforcers may need to intervene.
As a result, although we oppose broad market-wide reforms that would force divestiture or limit share ownership by large institutional investors, we do believe that antitrust enforcers should remain vigilant in scrutinizing coop- erative behavior facilitated by shareholders. This article analyzes the specific contexts in which coordinated anticompetitive effects resulting from low levels of common share ownership (less than 15 percent) are plausible and then assesses how the law can strike the difficult balance between procompe- titive and anticompetitive effects without unnecessarily chilling shareholder involvement in corporate governance. Our analysis is, by necessity, prelimi- nary because the application of Section 1 of the Sherman Act and Section 7 of the Clayton Act to particular factual situations will be context-specific.
With the shift from individual shareholding to holding through investment intermediaries, the distribution of shareholding has been transformed. In place of the old “dispersed ownership” model in which individuals directly owned shares, the overwhelming proportion of shares in U.S. corporations are now held by institutional investors of one sort or another: mutual funds, insurance companies, pension funds, and endowments. One consequence of this “de- retailization” has been increased concentration of shareholdings. In recent years, with the increased popularity of passive investment strategies (e.g., in- dex funds and exchange-traded funds (ETFs)), the fund families that manage the largest index funds and ETFs—BlackRock, Vanguard, and State Street— have become the largest shareholders of many or even most public compa- nies. Often the “big three” will each hold in excess of 5 percent of the shares and many times more than 6 or even 7 percent.