August is usually a quiet month in Washington. But August 2022 changed the course of administration. Through the Inflation Reduction Act, Congress enacted hundreds of billions of dollars in appropriations and forgone revenue to support sectors key to the clean energy transition. And just a week earlier, Congress passed the CHIPS and Science Act, appropriating nearly $53 billion for investments into the U.S. semiconductor industry. The bulk of that spending came to the Department of Commerce to offer financial incentives to companies to build and expand domestic fabrication facilities. Congress and regulators imposed a variety of conditions on firms receiving incentives from this pool of funds. Yet the core statutory authority underlying these transactions was striking in its scope: Commerce was to “enter into agreements … and other transactions as may be necessary and on such terms as the Secretary considers appropriate.”
Commentators such as Ezra Klein and Paul Krugman have hailed this turn towards “industrial policy” as the dawn of a new political-economic paradigm. And there is reason to believe that this kind of marketcrafting is likely to remain salient in the years ahead. Across the ideological spectrum, lawmakers have increasingly embraced the case for sectoralism: the idea that that the size and operation of different industries matter to achieving public aims. Sectoralism rejects the notion that the best economic policy necessarily maximizes aggregate national wealth, under the assumption that resources and information will flow freely to their highest use-value across the economy. Under this view, for example, we might decide that we care deeply about the provision of quality childcare or ensuring sufficient domestic capacity to ramp up production of a key medical supply. In many such cases, simply buying or subsidizing a good or service without further intervention cannot produce the qualitative outcomes the public seeks.
Clearly, the normative questions that lawmakers will grapple with in enacting industrial policies are vast in scope. Industrial policy is also a broad category of statecraft and can be executed in many ways. Industrial policies can take the form of trade policies, regulatory standards that establish product quality standards, and educational policies that aim to train workers for particular jobs. For both political and procedural reasons, however, it has proven easier to enact industrial policy through discretionary spending than through other forms of lawmaking. So, while the battles over industrial policy are likely to be broad, the terrain on which they are fought is likely to be quite particular. Administration of grants and procurement contracts, loans and equity investments, forward commitments, and other transactions authority may well become the important sites of contestation.
The resurgence of industrial policy therefore has dramatic consequences not just for lawmakers but also for the administrative lawyers who will be tasked with effectuating such policies. The transition from utility commissions and rate-setting to rulemaking and standard-setting marked an epochal shift in administrative law’s main focus. The resurgence of industrial policy might mark yet another.
Administrative lawyers often conceive of their practice as ensuring that agencies operate with procedural fairness, within the four corners of their authorizing statutes. These goals are evidently relevant in the industrial policy context. Industrial policy frequently empowers the Executive Branch with dramatic authority to design sectoral interventions in the manner that best serves public ends. And yet, despite this, administrative law finds itself singularly ill-equipped to deal with the governance questions the new industrial policy raises.
In a recent article in the Harvard Law & Policy Review, Amy Kapczynski and I describe administrative law’s inadequacy for structuring how regulatory power in the industrial policy domain should be exercised. Dramatic changes in doctrine—with the Court’s recent decisions in Loper Bright and Corner Post cases in point—have unmoored the anchors as to what judicial review of agency decisionmaking ought to look like. But even had these changes not taken place, much of the industrial policy toolkit already sits uncomfortably within both statutory and administrative common law. Agencies’ decisions about how to spend lump-sum appropriations are presumptively unreviewable. Regulations related to grants and contracts are generally exempt from the APA’s notice-and-comment requirements. Even when judicial review is theoretically available, lack of an administrative record, timing issues, and lack of standing all present barriers to granting relief. Of course, this does not mean that courts will not intervene over industrial policy decisionmaking. But, when they do so, they may be acting on limited evidentiary bases and with unclear precedents, heightening uncertainty and hampering effective administration.